How Government Borrowing Affects Investment and the Trade Balance

Read this text on the national savings and investment identity concerning supply and demand. What role do budget surpluses and trade surpluses play? The United States has two main sources of financial capital: private savings (S) and public savings (T-G or taxes collected minus government spending). Foreign investment capital equals imports (M) minus exports (X).

When governments are borrowers in financial markets, there are three possible sources of funds from a macroeconomic point of view:

  1. households might save more;
  2. private firms might borrow less, and
  3. the additional funds for government borrowing might come from outside the country, from foreign financial investors.

Let's begin with a review of why one of these three options must occur and then explore how interest rates and exchange rates adjust to these connections.


The National Savings and Investment Identity

The national saving and investment identity, which we first introduced in The International Trade and Capital Flows chapter, provides a framework for showing the relationships between the sources of demand and supply in financial capital markets. The identity begins with a statement that must always hold true: the quantity of financial capital supplied in the market must equal the quantity of financial capital demanded.

The U.S. economy has two main sources of financial capital: private savings from inside the U.S. economy and public savings.

Total savings = Private savings (S) + Public savings (T – G)


These include the inflow of foreign financial capital from abroad. The inflow of savings from abroad is, by definition, equal to the trade deficit, as we explained in The International Trade and Capital Flows chapter. We can write this inflow of foreign investment capital as imports (M) minus exports (X). There are also two main sources of demand for financial capital: private sector investment (I) and government borrowing. Government borrowing in any given year is equal to the budget deficit, which we can write as the difference between government spending (G) and net taxes (T). Let's call this equation: 1.

Quantity supplied of financial capital = Quantity demanded of financial capital

Private savings + Inflow of foreign savings= Private investment + Government budget deficit

S + (M – X) =  I + (G –T)


Governments often spend more than they receive in taxes, and therefore, public savings (T – G) is negative. This causes a need to borrow money in the amount of (G – T) instead of adding to the nation's savings. If this is the case, we can view governments as demanders of financial capital instead of suppliers. In algebraic terms, we can rewrite the national savings and investment identity like this:

Private investment = Private savings + Public savings + Trade deficit

I =  S + (T – G) + (M – X)


Let's call this equation 2. We must accompany a change in any part of the national saving and investment identity by offsetting changes in at least one other part of the equation. We assume that the equality of quantity supplied and quantity demanded always holds. If the government budget deficit changes, then either private savings or investment or the trade balance - or some combination of the three - must change as well. Figure 18.2 shows the possible effects.

 Figure 18.2 Effects of Change in Budget Surplus or Deficit on Investment, Savings, and The Trade Balance Chart (a) shows the

Figure 18.2 Effects of Change in Budget Surplus or Deficit on Investment, Savings, and The Trade Balance Chart (a) shows the potential results when the budget deficit rises (or budget surplus falls). Chart (b) shows the potential results when the budget deficit falls (or budget surplus rises).


What about Budget Surpluses and Trade Surpluses?

The national saving and investment identity must always hold true because, by definition, the quantity supplied and quantity demanded in the financial capital market must always be equal. However, the formula will look somewhat different if the government budget is in deficit rather than surplus or if the balance of trade is in surplus rather than deficit. For example, in 1999 and 2000, the U.S. government had budget surpluses, although the economy was still experiencing trade deficits. When the government was running budget surpluses, it was acting as a saver rather than a borrower and supplying rather than demanding financial capital. As a result, we would write the national saving and investment identity during this time as follows:

Quantity supplied of financial capital = Quantity demanded of financial capital

Private savings + Trade deficit + Government surplus = Private investment

S + (M – X) + (T – G) = I


Let's call this equation 3. Notice that this expression is mathematically the same as equation 2, except the savings and investment sides of the identity have simply flipped sides.

During the 1960s, the U.S. government was often running a budget deficit, but the economy was typically running trade surpluses. Since a trade surplus means that an economy is experiencing a net outflow of financial capital, we would write the national saving and investment identity as:

Quantity supplied of financial capital = Quantity demanded of financial capital

Private savings = Private investment + Outflow of foreign savings + Government budget deficit

S = I + (X – M) + (G – T)


Instead of the balance of trade representing part of the supply of financial capital, which occurs with a trade deficit, a trade surplus represents an outflow of financial capital leaving the domestic economy and invested elsewhere in the world.

Quantity supplied of financial capital = Quantity demanded of financial capital demand

Private savings = Private investment + Government budget deficit + Trade surplus

S = I + (G – T) + (X – M)


We assume that the point of these equations is that the national saving and investment identity always holds. When you write these relationships, it is important to engage your brain and think about what is on the supply and demand side of the financial capital market before you start your calculations.

As you can see in Figure 18.3, the Office of Management and Budget shows that the United States has consistently run budget deficits since 1977, with the exception of 1999 and 2000. What is alarming is the dramatic increase in budget deficits that has occurred since 2008, which in part reflects declining tax revenues and increased safety net expenditures due to the Great Recession. While deficits were controlled as the economy began to recover in the mid-2010s, the budget deficit increased again in 2020 during the pandemic, and forecasters expect deficits to remain high for the foreseeable future. (Recall that T is net taxes. When the government must transfer funds back to individuals for safety net expenditures like Social Security and unemployment benefits, budget deficits rise.) These deficits have implications for the future health of the U.S. economy.

 Figure 18.3 United States On-Budget, Surplus, and Deficit, 1952–2020 ($ billions) The United States has run a budget deficit

Figure 18.3 United States On-Budget, Surplus, and Deficit, 1952–2020 ($ billions) The United States has run a budget deficit for over 30 years, with the exception of 1999 and 2000. Military expenditures, entitlement programs, and the decrease in tax revenue coupled with increased safety net support during the Great Recession are major contributors to the dramatic increases in the deficit after 2008.


A rising budget deficit may result in a fall in domestic investment, a rise in private savings, or a rise in the trade deficit. The following modules discuss each of these possible effects in more detail.


Source: Rice University, https://openstax.org/books/principles-macroeconomics-3e/pages/18-1-how-government-borrowing-affects-investment-and-the-trade-balance
Creative Commons License This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 License.

Last modified: Thursday, September 21, 2023, 8:56 AM