Price-Setting Models for Innovative Products
Site: | Saylor Academy |
Course: | BUS606: Operations and Supply Chain Management |
Book: | Price-Setting Models for Innovative Products |
Printed by: | Guest user |
Date: | Thursday, 3 April 2025, 10:08 PM |
Description
Modern organizations have abundant choices in selecting the right product supply chain. Functional products are items that are purchased regularly, are widely available from multiple sources, and have long life cycles. Alternatively, innovative products are new to the marketplace, have unpredictable demand, and usually have short life cycles.
Read this article. Researchers suggest that products belong to either a functional or innovative category, where innovative products are much more challenging to price. What innovative products do you own, and how do you know you are getting the value you paid for?
Abstract
In this paper, we consider a manufacturer who produces and sells a kind of innovative product in the monopoly market environment. Because the life cycle of an innovative product is usually shorter than its procurement lead time, one unique demand quantity (scenario) will occur in the selling season; thus, there is only one chance for the manufacturer to determine both optimal production quantity and optimal sale price. Considering this one-time feature of such a decision problem, a price-setting newsvendor model for innovative products is proposed. Different to the existing price-setting newsvendor models, the proposed models determine the optimal production quantity and sale price based on some specific state (scenario) which is most applicable for the manufacturer. The theoretical analysis provides managerial insights into the manufacturers’ behaviors in a monopoly market of an innovative product, and several phenomena in the luxury goods market are well explained.
Keywords: price-setting newsvendor; one-shot decision theory; innovative product; scenario; behavioral operations research
Source: Xiuyan Ma, https://www.mdpi.com/2227-7390/7/9/814/htm
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 License.
Introduction
As a fundamental and important inventory management problem, the newsvendor models have been extensively reviewed. The newsvendor model applies to various decision-making contexts, such as inventory decisions, supply chain contracting and healthcare management. It examines a particular choice under uncertainty: A decision maker sets a quantity to match an uncertain variable, either too high or too low leads to a loss. Although the essential newsvendor model characterizes a one-variable problem that emphasizes operational efficiency, it also is foundational to the development of joint-decision models for defining and characterizing the operations/marketing interface, that is a decision maker sets not only a quantity, but a price to match a price depending uncertain variable. In this context, the newsvendor problem becomes a price-setting newsvendor problems.
Starting with the seminal work of Fisher, researchers in supply chain management have extensively studied innovative products. As Fisher's definition, products essentially belong to either innovative or functional categories. Compared with functional products, innovative products have shorter life cycles and unpredictable demands. For innovative products, before the selling season, the manufacturer has to make a decision on both the production quantity and the retail price, i.e., the pricing-setting newsvendor problem.
For one kind of innovative product, since the lifecycle is usually shorter than its procurement lead time, there is usually only one non-repeating selling season, only one demand quantity (scenario) will occur in only one selling season. Therefore, only one scenario would make sense for evaluating the newsvendor decisions related to the innovative product. Guo firstly raised the one-shot decision theory (OSDT), in which only some particular scenario is utilized to evaluate the objective function, for dealing with such problems. The one-shot decision process is separated into two steps. The first step is to seek an appropriate scenario from all possible states for each alternative. This scenario is called as the focus point of the alternative. The second step is to evaluate the alternatives by the satisfaction levels incurred by the focus points for obtaining the optimal alternative. Based on OSDT, plenty kinds of decision-making problems have been researched. Guo and Ma proposed the newsvendor model for innovative products where the manufacturer was in a perfect, competitive market so that the sale price was given. Zhu and Guo analyzed the approaches to bi-level programming problems. Recently, Guo proposed the focus theory of choice (FTC) that is a generalization of OSDT and provided axiomation to a decision-making procedure under risk and uncertainty. Several well-known anomalies, such as the Allais, Ellsberg and St. Petersburg paradoxes are well explained in the models. Based on the FTC, Guo and Zhu presented the focus programming, which provides a fundamental alternative for stochastic optimization problems.
There is a growing literature to show the decision biases in the real-world phenomena and experimental observations of the newsvendor type problems. The current models (e.g., risk-neutral, risk-seeking and risk-averse) do not describe actual decisions in the newsvendor setting very well and "another theory is needed". Therefore, it is interesting and valuable to continue examining the behaviors of the manufacturer in a monopolistic market with alternative decision rules or theories. We consider the manufacturer who produces and sells a kind of innovative product in a monopoly market. The manufacturer has only chance to decide both the production quantity and the sale price with the uncertain demand. The OSDT based price-setting newsvendor model is proposed for this situation. In this model, the decisions of the retail price and ordering quantity are both structured by the OSDT. It is a substantial extension of the research and enriches the literature of newsvendor.
The contributions are as follows:
First, the existing price-setting newsvendor models seek optimal inventories and prices to maximize the expected utilities (EUs). In these models, choosing a production quantity is equal to choosing a lottery (or a probability distribution). Because of the short life cycle of an innovative product, producing/selling such a product is a typical one-time decision. The risk attitudes of newsvendors for such a one-time decision are reflected by the differences of the utility functions (linear, concave and convex ones). Based on the OSDT, we build the price-setting newsvendor models and argue that the different behaviors of the manufacturers caused by their different personalities. According to the types of scenario (demand), they focus on the manufacturers can be divided into active, passive, apprehensive and daring types. The scenario-based price-setting newsvendor model is proposed, which is a fundamentally different model for analyzing the newsvendor problems in a monopoly market of an innovative product. Second, the theoretical analysis provides insights into the behaviors of manufacturers and several phenomena in the luxury goods market are well explained.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, the newsvendor models with the OSDT are introduced. In Section 3, the price-setting newsvendor model for innovative products is constructed. In Section 4, some theoretical analysis results are given, and several phenomena in the luxury goods market are examined. In Section 5, the numerical example is performed to demonstrate the proposed models. In Section 6, the conclusions and future research directions are given.
Newsvendor Models with the OSDT
In this section, the decision-making procedure for a retailer of innovative products is introduced. Before the selling season, the retailer must decide the order quantity q. For one unit of the innovative product, the wholesale price is , and the retail price is
and
. If there is an excess, the unit salvage price is
. The unit opportunity cost is
for the shortage. The retailer's profit function is as follows:
(1)
The demand function of the innovative product is described by a random variable and the probability mass (density) function is
.
Definition 1. Given the probability function for random vector and
be a function satisfying
(2) is the relative likelihood degree of
if
for
and
for
. For a retailer, his/her satisfaction levels towards profits are represented by the satisfaction function.
Definition 2. The satisfaction function is a strictly increasing function of the profit ,
(3)
Obviously, the relative likelihood degrees and the satisfaction levels can be utilized to describe the relative position of the probabilities and the payoffs, respectively.
Usually, because of the short life cycle of the innovative product, there is only one chance given to the retailer to determine his/her order quantity and a unique demand will appear accordingly. Therefore, before ordering products, the retailer has to meditate which demand should be factored in. We take into account four types of demands (scenarios) for each order quantity with contemplating the likelihood degrees and the satisfaction levels, that is the demands with the higher satisfaction and likelihood (Type I), the lower satisfaction and higher likelihood (Type II), the higher satisfaction and lower likelihood (Type III), the lower satisfaction and likelihood (Type IV). It is intuitively acceptable that active, passive, daring and apprehensive retailers are inclined to take into account Type I, Type II, Type III and Type IV demands, respectively. Therefore, we call Type I, Type II, Type III and Type IV demands active, passive, daring and apprehensive focus points, respectively (shown in Table 1). Which kind of focus point is taking into account reflects the personality of the retailer under demand uncertainty.
Table 1. Four different focus points.
satisfaction | |||
higher | lower | ||
likelihood | higher | active focus point | passive focus point |
lower | daring focus point | Apprehensive focus point |
Following operators are introduced to characterize the focus points.
Demands | 350 | 450 | 550 | 650 | 750 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
likelihood degrees | 0.22 | 0.35 | 1.00 | 0.73 | 0.29 |
Demands | ||||||
350 | 450 | 550 | 650 | 750 | ||
Orders | 350 | 1050 | 650 | 250 | −150 | −550 |
450 | 450 | 1350 | 950 | 550 | 150 | |
550 | −150 | 750 | 1650 | 1250 | 850 | |
650 | −170 | 150 | 1050 | 1950 | 1550 | |
750 | −1350 | −450 | 450 | 1350 | 2250 |
Demands | ||||||
350 | 450 | 550 | 650 | 750 | ||
Orders | 350 | 0.67 | 0.56 | 0.44 | 0.33 | 0.22 |
450 | 0.50 | 0.75 | 0.64 | 0.53 | 0.42 | |
550 | 0.33 | 0.58 | 0.83 | 0.72 | 0.61 | |
650 | 0.17 | 0.42 | 0.67 | 0.92 | 0.81 | |
750 | 0.00 | 0.25 | 0.50 | 0.75 | 1.00 |
Order Quantities | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
350 | 450 | 550 | 650 | 750 | |
Active | 550 | 550 | 550 | 650 | 650 |
Passive | 650 | 650 | 450 | 450 | 550 |
Apprehensive | 750 | 750 | 350 | 350 | 350 |
Daring | 350 | 450 | 750 | 750 | 750 |
In step 2, the optimal order quantities are chosen on the basis of satisfaction levels of focus points. The satisfaction levels for each order quantity with different types of focus points is easily calculated (see Table 6). Using (10–13), we get the optimal active, passive, apprehensive and daring order quantities, that is 650, 550, 450, and 750, respectively.
Order Quantities | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
350 | 450 | 550 | 650 | 750 | |
Active | 0.44 | 0.64 | 0.83 | 0.92 | 0.75 |
Passive | 0.33 | 0.53 | 0.58 | 0.42 | 0.50 |
Apprehensive | 0.22 | 0.42 | 0.33 | 0.17 | 0.00 |
Daring | 0.67 | 0.75 | 0.61 | 0.81 | 1.00 |
Price-Setting Newsvendor Models Based on OSDT
In the following model, a manufacturer who produces and sells an innovative product in the monopoly market is considered. Before selling season, the manufacturer produces units at unit cost W and setup cost is assumed to be zero. We consider the following widely used linear inverse demand function.
(15)
where shows the limit demand when the retail price equals to
, and
represents the decreasing of demand when the retail price increases by one unit. We call a as the price sensitivity of market demand. The demand's uncertainty is described by the parameter b with probability density function
. The profit function is with the retail price and the production quantity as the decision variables. With considering (1), it can be expressed as:
(16)
If one considers Definitions 1 and 2, then we have the relative likelihood function of , i.e.,
and the satisfaction function, i.e.,
. Similar to the newsvendor model, the following types of focus points are considered.
Active focus point: For retail price and production quantity
, the active focus point is
(17)
is the focused demand value with the relatively high likelihood degree and satisfaction level for the production quantity
.
Passive focus point: For retail price and production quantity
, the passive focus point is
(18)
is the focused demand value with the relatively high likelihood degree and relatively low satisfaction level for the production quantity
.
Apprehensive focus point: For retail price and production quantity
, the apprehensive focus point is
(19)
is the focused demand value with the relatively low likelihood degree and satisfaction level for the production quantity
.
Daring focus point: For retail price and production quantity
, the daring focus point is
(20)
is the focused demand value with the relatively low likelihood degree and relatively high satisfaction level for a production quantity
.
The sets of the four types of focus points of the retail price and production quantity
are denoted as
,
,
and
, respectively. The optimal production quantities for the manufacturers are
(21)
(22)
(23)
(26)
Analysis Results for the OSDT Based Price-Setting Newsvendor Models
We suppose the following assumption in this section.
Assumption: The probability density function is a unimodal function defined on the interval
, the mode is
and
.
From Equation (15), we know and
are the lowest demand and highest demand;
is the most possible demand. Since the demand is within
, the reasonable supply should lie on the same interval. Therefore, the manufacturer's highest profit is
(29)
that is, the manufacturer produces the most , meanwhile, the demand happens to be the same as production quantity. The lowest profit is the minimum profit of two situations, one is the manufacturer produces the highest, however, the demand happens to be the least, the profit is
; the other is the manufacturer produces the least, however, the demand happens to be the most, the profit is
. Because of the high cost and margin of innovative products, it is reasonable to assume
, which leads to
(30)
For a fixed retail price , the manufacturer's satisfaction level is the continuous strictly increasing function of profit
, that is
(31)
(31) provides a general formulation of the satisfaction function where the satisfaction level of the highest profit is 1, and the lowest profit is 0.
We have the following lemmas and propositions. The proofs are shown in the Appendix A. The following proposition indicates the relationships between the four types of manufacturers' focused profits.
Proposition 1. For any , we have the following relationships between the four types of manufacturers' focused profits.
(32)
Proposition 1 shows that the daring manufacturer always imagines a higher profit than the active manufacturer; meanwhile, the active manufacturer imagines a higher profit than a passive manufacturer, and the passive manufacturer imagines a higher profit than an apprehensive manufacturer. Such conclusions are interesting and intuitively acceptable.
Since the demand is not less than zero, it is reasonable that and
. In what follows, we suppose the satisfaction level is a linear function of profit, that is
(33)
The optimal retail price for four types of retailers is given in Propositions 2–5, below.
Proposition 2. If ,
and
are of class
, and
and
hold, then the active profit function
is concave. Furthermore, if
, then the unique solution of
lies on the interval
, which is the optimal active retail price
.
Proposition 2 shows that the active profit function's concavity is related to the price sensitivity of the market demand. Propositions 3–5 examine the concavities of passive, apprehensive and daring profit functions, respectively; and provide optimal passive, apprehensive and daring retail prices.
Proposition 3. If is of class
for
and
and
is of class
for
,
and
and
(where
,
,
) holds, then the passive profit function
is concave. Furthermore, the unique solution of
lies on the interval
, which is the optimal passive retail price
.
Proposition 3 points out that the passive profit function's concavity depends on the relationship between the changes in retail price of the optimal passive production quantity and of its corresponding focused demand value.
Proposition 4. The apprehensive profit function is concave. Furthermore, if
, then the optimal apprehensive retail price is the unique solution of
within
.
Proposition 5. The daring profit function is concave. If
, then the optimal daring retail price is
, and lies on the interval
; otherwise,
.
Propositions 4 and 5 show that the apprehensive and daring profit functions and
are always concave. Assume
and
are concave, the optimal retail prices lie on the interval
, we have Proposition 6 and 7, as follows.
Proposition 6. We have the following relationships between the four types of manufacturers' optimal retail prices.
(34)
Proposition 6 tells that the daring manufacturer has the highest optimal retail price; the active manufacturer has a higher optimal price than the passive manufacturer, and the apprehensive manufacturer has the lowest optimal retail price. Such conclusions can be used for distinguishing the type of the manufacturer according to the observed retail price which he/she has set and also can predict the retail price which he/she will set if knowing the personality of the manufacturer. Let us look at the supporting evident form the Wall Street Journal which reported that the manufacturers who sell ultraluxury brands are actually risk-takers, they are raising prices to distinguish their products from other luxury goods, and they believe that the rich consumers are willing to accept such prices.
Proposition 7. The optimal active, passive, apprehensive and daring retail prices are decreasing in .
Proposition 7 shows that the with the increase of the market demand's price sensitivity, the manufacturer will charge a lower retail price; that is to say, whichever the manufacturer's type is, decreasing the price sensitivity of the demand is efficient for charging a high retail price in the innovative product market. Interestingly, the following fact supports the above conclusion. It is from the report of Accenture® that the luxury manufacturers that build brands on the image and lifestyle are able to withstand bigger competitive pricing differences than manufacturers who build their brands on the price. It future explained that "a well-known luxury manufacturer incorporated the price sensitivity metrics into its overall pricing and assortment strategy in recent years. The strategy has helped boost the company's profit margins to its highest level".
Numerical Example
A direct-sale store of a fashion company from France, located in Dalian, China, is going to sell a new design fashion clothes. The fashion store is a monopoly in the northeast China market. The unit cost , salvage price
and opportunity cost
are 7000, 1000 and 4000 (RMB), respectively. The market demand is related to the retail price, and we have
,
. Let us consider the store's pricing policies when
,
and
. As an example, let us see the details when
.
Suppose parameter 's probability density function is
. From Equation (15), the profit function is
(35)
For simplification, the satisfaction function is the normalization of . We obtain
,
,
and
;
,
,
and
. Similarly, we can obtain that when
,
,
,
,
,
,
,
and
; when
,
,
,
,
,
,
,
and
. The relationships between retail prices and profits when
,
and
are shown in Figure 1, Figure 2 and Figure 3, respectively.
Figure 1. Relationships between retail prices and profits when .
Figure 2. Relationships between retail prices and profits when .
Figure 3. Relationships between retail prices and profits when .
The numerical example shows three interesting phenomena. First, we observe that with the increasing of market demand's price sensitivity (the increase of parameter ), all of the four types of manufacturers charge the lower retail prices. Second, the numerical example indicates that for any
,
. That is the focused profits of the daring manufacturer are higher than the ones of active one; the focused profits of the active manufacturer are higher than the ones of the passive manufacturer; the focused profits of the passive manufacturer are higher than the ones of the apprehensive manufacturer. Third, we have
which shows that the daring manufacturer has the highest optimal retail price; the active manufacturer has a higher optimal price than the passive manufacturer, and the apprehensive manufacturer has the lowest optimal retail price. The first result is similar to Reference, however, since we model the behaviors of different types of manufacturers, the second and third results are original. Such conclusions are in accordance with phenomena in the real business world.
Conclusions
Considering the one-time feature of the manufacturer's decision-making for producing and pricing the innovative product in a monopoly market, we propose the price-setting newsvendor model for an innovative product with the OSDT. Unlike the price-setting newsvendor model with the EU where the optimal retail price and production quantity are obtained based on the weighted average of all possible payoffs' utilities, the price-setting newsvendor model with OSDT determines the optimal retail price and production quantity based on the satisfaction level of its focus point (scenario). Clearly, the proposed model is scenario-based, which is radically different from the lottery-based models.
Active, passive, apprehensive and daring manufacturers are considered in this research. If the profit functions are concave, we have the following conclusions:
The daring manufacturer always imagines a higher profit than the active manufacturer; meanwhile, the active manufacturer imagines higher than a passive manufacturer, and the passive manufacturer imagines higher than an apprehensive manufacturer.
The daring manufacturer has the highest optimal retail price; the active manufacturer has a higher optimal price than the passive manufacturer, and the apprehensive manufacturer has the lowest optimal retail price.
Whichever the manufacturer's type is, decreasing the price sensitivity of the demand is efficient for charging a high retail price in the innovative product market.
Such theoretical results are consistent with the phenomena in the real business world and provide managerial insights into different types of manufacturer's behaviors in a monopoly market. Using the obtained analytic results, several phenomena in the luxury goods market have been well explained. In the near future, we will analyze the channel coordination and personality information sharing in the supply chain.