Read this article about the history of capitalism. Although the term capitalism was coined in the 19th century, its practices are much older.
Industrial Capitalism and Classical Critique in the Long Nineteenth Century
I
am jumping forward by one century. In Werner Sombart's and Max Weber's
analysis of capitalism, for example, there was much confidence in the
economic superiority and the economic rationality of capitalism.
However, these authors did not see capitalism anymore as a carrier of
human progress, moral improvement, and civilizational uplift. On the
contrary, liberals like Weber feared the increasing rigidity of the
system that he anticipated would threaten human freedom by coercing
economic actors to function according to its increasingly compulsive
rules of relentless competition and growth, or to drop out of the market
altogether. Among conservatives as well as on the left, capitalism was
seen as an irresistible force of erosion: Custom was seen to be replaced
by contract, Gemeinschaft by Gesellschaft, the traditional by the
modern, and social bonds by the market. On the right, anti-capitalism
frequently went hand in hand with anti-liberalism and anti-Semitism,
particularly after the Great Depression of the 1870s. The socialist
critique of capitalism was different, and the most powerful one. On the
one hand, it attacked the exploitation of labor by capital, the increase
of social inequality, the lack of a fair deal, and alienation and
suppression in the workplace. On the other hand, it predicted the
decline of capitalism due to its internal contradictions and its
replacement by something new; namely socialism. Many of those who did
not enjoy this perspective did not contest it either, but were fearful
of its arrival.
The discourse of ascent and flourishing had
largely been replaced by a discourse of fall and decline. I mentioned at
the beginning that this was the intellectual, mental situation in which
the concept of capitalism emerged, first as a critical and polemical
concept; soon to be turned into a powerful analytical tool. The concept
emerged, one might say, as a concept of difference. It was used to
identify and critically underline certain features of the present, in
contrast to what it was thought to have been in previous times, and to
what it might become under socialism in the future. The contrast with a
selectively commemorated past and with an imagined future was
constitutive for the emergence of the concept "capitalism," and in a way
this mechanism still works today when it comes to more basic
discussions of capitalism.10
How can we explain this change in
the evaluation of capitalism between the late eighteenth, late
nineteenth, and early twentieth century; this change of mood from
appreciation to criticism? Let me pick out three relevant issues.
1.
While Adam Smith had known capitalism before industrialization,
nineteenth-century capitalism mainly spread in the form of industrial
capitalism, based on the factory system and wage labor en masse. Now the
capitalist principle of commodification was fully extended into the
sphere of work and labor, to the activities of human beings on a grand
scale. Work relations were becoming capitalist, which meant that they
became dependent on changing market mechanisms, subject to ever stricter
calculation, and subordinated to supervision by employers or managers.
At the same time, industrial wealth was accumulated to an unprecedented
degree, due to an increasing need for large-scale fixed capital in
mines, factories, railways, and other institutions of industrial
capitalism. As a consequence, wealth differences became more visible,
and stricter controls of profitability over time were felt to be needed
and were practiced by employers and managers. The class difference had
been built into capitalism as a potentiality from the start; now it
became more manifest. It could be directly experienced, widely observed,
and critically discussed. This was the constellation - industrial
capitalism with the factory system, large-scale capital accumulation,
and wage labor as a mass phenomenon - which served as the empirical base
for the classic narratives of Marx and Engels, and for the rise of
labor movements critical of or hostile to (basic elements of)
capitalism.11
2. Technological and organizational innovation
became much more important, frequent, and regular under industrial
capitalism than ever before. In other words, what Joseph A. Schumpeter
would later call "creative destruction" became the rule and a widespread
experience. Factories pushed aside cottage work in the spinning of yarn
and the weaving of clothes. Steamships replaced traditional forms of
transportation on rivers, canals, and oceans. Producers of electrical
installations gained superiority over the providers of gas-powered
lighting. This was a process opening up new opportunities to many and
new roads towards success, but there were also numerous losers at the
same time. Ascent and decline are mechanisms anchored right at the core
of capitalism. Permanent competition, sustained insecurity, and
threatening dangers were institutionalized; and resented. There were
many losers. All of this came in cycles, with ups and downs, booms and
busts. Nineteenth-century crises impacted on large segments of the
populations. The crises helped to delegitimize capitalism and increase
anti-capitalist resentment.12
3. There was a rise of
expectations. Partly as a precondition and partly as a consequence of
capitalist industrialization, previous patterns of social control were
loosened, the standard of living was raised, fast historical change was
experienced, and human affairs appeared - in fact proved - to be
changeable. The level of education was raised, and public spaces emerged
in which intellectuals and the media played a dynamic, frequently a
critical, role. As a consequence, people became less patient, more
demanding, and more critical. In a way, capitalism's critique followed
from capitalism's success; something analyzed by Joseph Schumpeter and
Albert Hirschman as capitalism's propensity to undermine itself.
All
of this had surfaced by the end of the nineteenth and the start of the
twentieth century, very much in contrast to the period of Adam Smith.
While capitalism developed its strengths and powerfully expanded - both
internally (into different spheres of life) and externally (towards
different parts of the world) - its image darkened, its evaluation
became increasingly pessimistic, and its past and its present were
heavily criticized.