Read this article about "China's Great Proletarian Cultural Revolution". It marked a complex refashioning of Chinese labor relations and politics.
Reforms in the Labour Market: Enforcing Dualism
In addition to population transfers, another major element of the central government's recovery programme was a change in the recruitment of urban labour. Between 1962 and 1965, the CCP established the already-mentioned dual system in the labour market, as well as an equivalent system in education. The reasoning behind this move was simple.
Many factories
required new workers in order to meet their post-famine production
targets. However, the central government was reluctant to increase the
number of people on the state's payroll; a move that had backfired so
spectacularly during the Great Leap. Between 1960 and 1963, the
workforce in state-owned enterprises had decreased from 59 to 43
million, releasing some of the pressure on the urban welfare system.
Some of these losses had been absorbed by the collective enterprises,
where the workforce had increased from 9 to 11 million, but the overall
number of workers had still dropped, and more labour had to be found
from somewhere.
It was soon realized that one way to control
government spending while enlarging the workforce was to allow an
increase in the number of temporary workers. Short-term work had existed
alongside lifetime employment since 1949. A decision by the Labour
Department in 1959 had distinguished between three forms of urban work:
long-term employment, temporary contract work undertaken by urban
workers, and a system of "peasant-workers" recruited from the
countryside for short-term work in factories.26 Now, the government
dramatically expanded the number of workers in the latter two
categories. "Peasant-workers" were an especially useful resource, since
although their wages were higher than the average rural income, they
remained poorly paid compared with regular urban workers.
It was
clear from the outset that peasant-workers were not to be allowed to
become part of the permanent urban workforce. A 1965 report by the
Labour Department about the situation in Sichuan Province expressed
concern that if wages for young peasant-workers were set too high, they
would cause tension in the villages after their return. The report also
recommended that production brigades should be able to claim
compensation for work lost as a consequence of members taking temporary
jobs outside agriculture.27 Both these conclusions rested on the
assumption that a peasant-worker was and would remain part of his or her
rural community, with no prospect of earning admission to the urban
world. Although temporary workers were a minority, they were
nevertheless a significant part of the urban workforce in the 1960s. By
the end of 1965, China had over 33 million permanent workers and 3.18
million urban contract workers; an increase of 540,000 over the previous
year. Another two million people were employed as peasant-workers. A
contemporary report by the State Statistics Bureau praised the dual
labour market for allowing urban work units to replace many permanent
workers with temporary staff.28
In expanding the dual labour
market, the government never planned to abolish the "iron rice bowl",
but it did intend for a significant number of workers to be temporarily
employed and denied access to the welfare state. From 1964, President
Liu Shaoqi was an important advocate for the dual system in the labour
market and in education. In a speech on the topic, Liu argued that while
the iron rice bowl was the gold standard, it introduced problems by
making it difficult to "withdraw" workers; that is, to fire them. For
seasonal tasks, temporary employment was a more desirable route. As Liu
put it, "If there is work, they come. If there is not, they can go
home".29 Liu argued against future increases in the permanent workforce,
and he even suggested that entire sectors might become the exclusive
preserve of temporary workers. Discussing the mining industry, Liu noted
that life underground could lead to severe health problems, and he
proposed that workers should be recruited only to work in the mines for a
few years before being mandatorily discharged. While he was careful to
frame his argument in terms of workers' interests, "mandatory discharge"
would have had the convenient side effect of turning a whole industry
into short-term contract work. Liu's speech was rooted above all not in
the socialist logic of worker entitlements, but in the government's
desire to reduce costs.
In sum, the years between 1962 and 1966
saw a deepening of the urban-rural divide, resulting from a deliberate
reduction in the number of people entitled to access the urban welfare
state and stricter enforcement of the hukou registration system. A side
effect of these policies was to limit social mobility for the rural
population. Within the cities, the gap between the permanent and
temporary workforce also widened. Nevertheless, the party leadership
remained united behind the new measures, and it is notable that Mao
never questioned the hukou system in his lifetime, or the various
programmes to reduce the urban population.