Regional Trading Blocs
Site: | Saylor Academy |
Course: | BUS613: Advanced International Business |
Book: | Regional Trading Blocs |
Printed by: | Guest user |
Date: | Sunday, September 15, 2024, 3:43 PM |
Description
Regional trading blocs have become common in recent decades. They remove trade borders between neighboring countries to expand local markets and bolster trade by streamlining regulations, tariffs, and economic policies. These blocs can also come in the form of customs unions, which essentially create one shared market between several countries and dictate trade policies between countries in the union and those outside it.
A customs union (CU) is a form of trade agreement under which certain countries preferentially grant tarifffree market access to each other's imports and agree to apply a common set of external tariffs to imports from the rest of the world. That is, they enter into a free trade agreement (FTA) and apply a common external tariff (CET) schedule to imports from nonmembers.1 A CU can be thought of as a deeper form of integration than an FTA, generally requiring more coordination and a greater loss of autonomy.
The aims of this chapter are to provide, from an economics perspective, an overview of the key features of CUs and to examine some design issues that may be of interest to policy makers and (nonspecialist) analysts. The discussions are meant to be relatively conceptual and nontechnical, but real-world illustrations are provided when available.
To begin with, the main economic costs and benefits of opting for a CU, relative to those for an FTA, are discussed, and selected issues regarding the design and determinants of a common external tariff are examined. Although a number of arguments seem to suggest that CUs may be subject to more protectionist pressures than FTAs, the existing literature does not provide an unequivocal answer. There then follows a conceptual discussion of the implications of the various administrative options related to the collection and sharing of customs duties; this, it is shown, is not only a technical issue, but also (and perhaps more important) a question of trust among member countries. The chapter concludes with an overview of a number of systemic aspects of CUs. Readers interested in the more operational and detailed aspects of CUs are referred to the excellent surveys in Development Network Africa (2007).
Source: Jean-Pierre Chauffour and Jean-Christophe Maur, https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/2329/634040PUB0Pref00Box0361517B0PUBLIC0.pdf
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 License.
A Special Case of PTA CUs have been around for a long time and were once more prevalent than FTAs. Early efforts toward economic integration were generally driven by the desire to establish a political union, and the members were willing to relinquish some political autonomy. Early examples include the Zollverein, formed in 1834 by several German principalities, which turned out to be a step toward political unification, and the 1847 customs union between Moldavia and Walachia, a precursor to the creation of Romania.
More recently, CUs appear to have become less popular, at least with respect to the number of arrangements. As is thoroughly documented by Acharya et al. (ch. 2 in this volume), almost 85 percent of the regional integration arrangements notified to the World Trade Organization (WTO) through 2009 consisted of FTAs. This trend reflects the nature of the current wave of regionalism, which has been broadly characterized by smaller crossregional deals, flexibility, selectivity, and, most important, speed. Recent FTAs are inclined to be pragmatic and to focus more on strategic commercial market access and less on geographic considerations or political ambitions. They generally involve a small number of partners (frequently, just two), which are often geographically distant from each other. They tend to achieve significant preferential and reciprocal trade liberalization within a short time while simultaneously preserving a member's sovereignty over its trade policy vis-à-vis the rest of the world, including its option of joining other preferential trade agreements (PTAs).
By contrast, CUs usually involve a relatively large number of geographically contiguous countries (see table 5.1 for a selected listing). They generally take longer to negotiate and implement than do PTAs, and they entail a certain loss of policy-making autonomy. By 2009, they accounted for less than 10 percent of the regional integration arrangements notified to the WTO. CUs are less numerous than PTAs, but they generally have much larger memberships. They also tend to cover much larger geographic areas. The four main CUs in Latin America – the Central American Common Market (CACM), the Andean Community (CAN), the Caribbean Community (CARICOM), and the Southern Cone Common Market (Mercosur, Mercado Común del Sur) – include almost all the region's economies. The existing and planned CUs in Sub-Saharan Africa – the Economic and Monetary Community of Central Africa (Communauté Économique et Monétaire de l'Afrique Centrale), the East African Community (EAC), the Southern African Customs Union (SACU), the West African Economic and Monetary Union (WAEMU), the Economic Community of West African States (ECOWAS), the Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA), the Southern African Development Community (SADC), and the Economic Community of Central African States (ECCAS) – take in virtually every country in the region. Many countries in the Middle East and North Africa regions are members of the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC), the Arab Customs Union (ACU), or both. Although a CU is no longer the most popular option, it remains a central component of regional integration strategy in many developing regions. For many developing countries, the design and implementation of a CET, along with the elimination of intraregional trade barriers, continue to be key drivers of trade policy reform and to occupy an important place in policy debates. Given that customs duties constitute a significant source of government revenues in most of those countries, choosing the appropriate mechanism for collecting and allocating customs revenues is an important challenge for officials.
Agreement |
Date |
|
In force |
Southern African Customs Union (SACU) |
1910 |
Switzerland–Liechtenstein |
1924 |
European Union (EU) |
January 1, 1958 |
Central American Common Market (CACM) |
October 12, 1961 |
Caribbean Community (CARICOM) |
August 1, 1973 |
Andean Community (CAN) |
May 25, 1988 |
EU–Andorra |
July 1, 1991 |
Southern Cone Common Market (Mercosur, Mercado Común del Sur) |
November 29, 1991 |
Israel–Palestinian Authority |
1994 |
EU–Turkey |
January 1, 1996 |
Eurasian Economic Community (EAEC) |
October 8, 1997 |
Economic and Monetary Community of Central Africa (CEMAC, Communauté Économique et Monétaire de l'Afrique Centrale) |
June 24, 1999 |
West African Economic and Monetary Union/Union Économique et Monétaire Ouest-Africaine (WAEMU/UEMOA) |
January 1, 2000 |
East African Community (EAC) |
July 7, 2000 |
EU–San Marino |
April 1, 2002 |
Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) |
January 1, 2003 |
Customs Union of Belarus, Kazakhstan, and Russia |
July 1, 2010 Planned |
Arab Customs Union (ACU) |
2010 |
Southern African Development Community (SADC) |
2010 |
Economic Community of Central African States (ECCAS) |
2011 |
Economic Community of West African States (ECOWAS) |
2015 |
African Economic Community (AEC) |
2019 |
Arab Common Market (ACM) |
2020 |
Australia–New Zealand Closer Economic Relations Trade Agreement (ANZCERTA) |
2020 |
Chauffour and Maur discuss in detail the economic, societal, and political-economy motives for signing preferential trade agreements. A central issue is whether to opt for an FTA or a CU. By definition, both are preferential in nature and discriminate against third-party (nonmember) suppliers. The primary effect of a customs union, as with an FTA, is the expansion of trade flows among member countries, often at the expense of trade with nonmembers. This expansion, a consequence of the removal of the intraunion tariff barriers, can be decomposed into trade creation (more efficient suppliers in CU partners replace domestic suppliers of a given good) and trade diversion (more efficient third-party suppliers are displaced by less efficient suppliers located in partner countries, as a result of the discriminatory liberalization). As is well established in the literature, when trade diversion dominates trade creation, CUs and FTAs tend to be welfare reducing. The likelihood of significant trade diversion is closely related to the degree of discrimination associated with the agreement.
There are many possible rationales for choosing a CU over
an FTA, including political and economic ones. Some
regional groupings consider the establishment of a CU a
prerequisite for the future establishment of a political
union, or at least some deeper form of economic integration, such as a common market. The African Economic
Community provides an illustration. The Abuja Treaty of
1991 envisaged gradual implementation in the following
stages: (a) creation of regional blocs, by 1999; (b) strengthening of intrabloc integration and interbloc harmonization,
by 2007; (c) establishment of an FTA and then a CU in each
regional bloc, by 2017; (d) establishment of a continentwide
customs union, by 2019; (e) realization of a continentwide
African Common Market (ACM), by 2023; and (f) creation
of a continentwide economic and monetary union (and
thus also a currency union) and a parliament, by 2028.
Some groups, such as CARICOM, consider a CU to be
a useful way of pooling market power, coordinating trade
policies, and combining efforts to negotiate with the rest
of the world. The more intense degrees of coordination
and interaction associated with a CU can foster trust and
familiarity among the parties and may even decrease the
risk of conflicts, as has been the case with the European
Union (EU). The fact that the external tariff is agreed with
other parties through a legal agreement may help reformminded governments lock in their trade policies and can
shelter them from domestic lobbies.
On a lower level, a customs union can simply be a practical device for avoiding trade deflection while facilitating
more fluid trade flows among member states. In the simplest form of an FTA, member countries grant free trade to each
other but effectively maintain sovereignty over the conduct of trade policy vis-à-vis the rest of the world. Thus,
the tariffs charged to nonmember suppliers will vary
across members. This could lead to opportunities for trade
deflection – a situation in which goods from outside the
FTA are shipped to a low-tariff country and then transshipped tariff-free to the high-tariff country. Such roundabout shipping patterns, which have the sole purpose of
exploiting the existing tariff differential, are inherently
inefficient and can create friction among members.
One way to avoid such wasteful trade deflection is for
the members of the FTA to adopt a rules-of-origin system.
Rules of origin can take various forms, but generally they
require that goods (or value added) qualifying for tariff-free trade be produced within the FTA and that imports
from outside the FTA pay the tariff of the final destination country, even if they pass through another member
country. In practice,
rules of origin are particularly complex, and their implementation costs can be high. They necessitate significant
internal border controls to ensure compliance and to collect the relevant customs duties.
Another way to prevent trade deflection is to establish
a customs union, which would require all members to
apply the same external tariff to imports coming from
outside the union. Because of the common external tariff
(i.e., the absence of tariff differentials across members),
the potential for trade deflection and the need for intra -
union border inspections are, theoretically, minimized. In a
fully implemented customs union, it is no longer necessary to maintain internal border controls for customs
duty purposes or to design and implement the cumbersome and costly rules of origin that are necessary in a
free trade area in which members have different external
tariff structures. The simplification offered by a CU can
greatly facilitate cross-border trade, which is especially
relevant because existing CUs generally involve geographically contiguous countries, reflecting the traditional
objective of regional integration. In this regard, a CU can
approximate a larger single market (as compared with a
number of separate markets in an FTA), which can generate greater economies of scale, as well as procompetitive
pressures. These, in turn, can greatly benefit consumers
and can translate into lower business costs and enhanced
competitiveness for member countries.
As was mentioned earlier, the key difference between a CU
and an FTA is the need to adjust the tariff structure applied to third-party suppliers, at least for some members. Countries that join an FTA are not required to change the tariffs
they apply to imports from the rest of the world. What
will differentiate the effects of a CU from those of an FTA
will be the extent to which the external tariff is increased or
decreased by a given member with respect to a given good.
The net economic effect of a CU crucially depends on how
the adjustment of the external tariff affects the degree of
discrimination vis-à-vis nonmember countries.
In order to isolate the impact of a CU, it is useful to
start with a case in which an FTA is already in place (i.e.,
trade is already liberalized among the partners) and member countries are considering establishing a customs
union by harmonizing their external tariff duties. For
ease of presentation, the following discussion assumes
that two countries, A and B, are members of an FTA and
have decided to form a customs union. Without loss of
generality, it will be further assumed that, for a particular
good, A has a low tariff and B has a high one. Two possible cases are relevant and are examined here.
One possibility is that the agreed common external
tariff (CET) leads to a higher tariff rate for a given CU
member (say, country A). The bloc's degree of discrimination is thus enhanced, and the negative impact of trade
diversion caused by the FTA is exacerbated. This usually
happens when a less advanced member has to implement
a CET aimed at protecting the industries of a more developed member. In this case, consumers in country A will
lose because they have to pay higher prices for imports
from the rest of the world or switch to less efficient
suppliers from country B. Despite the higher external
tariff, the government in country A could collect less tariff
revenues if the higher degree of discrimination leads to a
greater propensity for switching the sourcing of imports
to duty-free, country B suppliers. Producers of the good in
A face less competition from the rest of the world but
more competition from B. In fact, the adoption of a high
tariff by A effectively extends the protection received by
country B producers to country A's markets. These producers may be the only ones to gain from the CU in this
scenario. In some cases, and in a more dynamic setting,
the expansion of the protected market may lead to some
tariff-jumping types of investment in the customs union,
motivated by the prospect of taking advantage of the
larger, more protected market.
Joining a CU may offer a second possibility to consolidate the existing tariff schedule and adopt a more liberal
trade regime. If the establishment of the CU yields a CET
that is lower than the pre-CU tariff (say, in country B), the
potential for trade diversion is reduced, or even reversed,
because there is less potential for switching suppliers. The discriminatory aspect of the FTA is, in a sense, diluted in
this case. Starting from an FTA situation, a decrease in B's
external tariff would have two effects, both working in the
same direction. First, the liberalization will directly
increase B's imports from the rest of the world (trade creation). Second, since it effectively dilutes the existing
preference margin, it will reduce the attractiveness of
sourcing from country A relative to sourcing from the rest
of the world (less trade diversion). By reversing the trade
diversion caused by the FTA (i.e., by inducing consumers
to switch from less efficient suppliers in A to more efficient ones in the rest of the world), country B's tariff
reduction will benefit its consumers. It could also help
increase government revenues. as dutiable imports from
the rest of the world expand (albeit at lower tariffs) and
as country B shifts to dutiable imports and away from
duty-free imports from A. Domestic producers will face
more competition from nonmembers, but this will be
offset by consumer gains resulting from lower prices and,
potentially, by higher tariff revenues. Although adopting
a lower CET may not lead to tariff-jumping investment, the
higher returns associated with the more liberal economic
environment could attract efficiency-seeking investments.
Krueger (1995) has argued that if the CET level is chosen as
the union's average tariff for a given commodity, an FTA
will not lead to more net trade creation than a CU. Furthermore, as long as the CET is set below the tariff level of
the high-cost country, an FTA will not be more welfare
enhancing than a CU.
In the actual implementation of a CET, an individual
CU member will generally have to increase its external
tariffs on certain products while decreasing them on others. The overall impact will depend on the balance. Kemp
and Wan (1976) demonstrate the existence of conditions
that suffice to ensure that a CU is welfare enhancing.
In particular, they show that if the CET is chosen so that
trade with the rest of the world is kept unchanged, then
following the establishment of a CU, welfare could potentially increase for all parties, including nonmembers, contingent on compensatory transfers. This increase occurs
because any additional trade between CU members would
be welfare-enhancing trade creation. Although this is an
important result, it is a "possibility" and does not guarantee
that the existing political-economy equilibrium will be a
welfare-enhancing one.
A well-designed and generally accepted CET is crucial for
the sustainability of a customs union. National tariffs must be harmonized at some agreed level, taking into
account not only the often-conflicting positions of each
member but also the various special interests within each
member. Setting the level of the CET in a consensual
manner could be a complex undertaking, entailing long
and involved negotiations between member country
governments, which are themselves subject to lobbying
by different interest groups. For instance, it took the EU
11 years (1957 to 1968) to complete its CET, and Mercosur
members took four years just to agree on their nonagricultural CET.
In many developing-country customs unions, the difficulties of agreeing on a common external tariff and on the
distribution of revenues have proved to be so great that
the resulting tariff schedules tend to include numerous
country or sector-specific exceptions and sensitive lists.
Although the CARICOM CET is largely in place, it allows
broad scope for tariff reductions and suspensions, as well
as for national derogations. The CET in Mercosur does
not cover all sectors, and it includes special regimes for the
automotive and sugar sectors. In some CUs, temporary
national exemptions are allowed – for example, EAC
members Kenya and Tanzania were allowed to unilaterally
reduce tariffs on selected grain imports. Derogations and
safeguards are widely used in most CUs. Not only can
these exceptions reduce the transparency and effectiveness
of the CU, but they also can complicate trade negotiations
and increase transaction costs. Furthermore, they reintroduce the potential for trade deflection – the very phenomenon that the CU is designed to prevent.
Like most other forms of regional integration agreements, a CU is inherently preferential and is, thus, discriminatory against third parties. As argued in the previous section, the economic impact of a CU will be closely related to
the degree of discrimination, which depends on the CET
level that is selected. The higher the CET, the more trade
diversionary will the union be. An important question is
thus whether a CU provides incentives for selecting higher
or lower external tariffs than those in, say, an FTA. The
existing theoretical and empirical literature does not provide
an unequivocal answer to this question. The result seems to
depend on the way preferences (or objective functions) are
aggregated across members and within each member.
A number of analysts have demonstrated that an FTA
may create downward pressure on external tariffs. For instance, Baldwin and Freund (ch. 6 in
this volume) argue that preferential trade liberalization
in an FTA tends to make tariffs against nonmembers'
third-nation tariffs more distortionary and that it creates
an incentive for FTA members to reoptimize their most favored nation (MFN) tariffs by making them more uniform and lower. (This is referred to as the "uniform tax
rate principle"). In a related fashion, if trade diversion
becomes apparent (i.e., if a country sees itself importing
a good from a partner country at a higher cost than the
cost of similar goods from nonmembers), an FTA member has the flexibility to cut tariffs on these third-party
imports. Similarly, the potential for trade deflection may
lead high-tariff countries to cut tariffs to just below the level
of their partners' rates to prevent imports from going
through low-tariff countries that would otherwise capture
the tariff revenue. In addition, lowering import tariffs on
inputs used in producing exports to other FTA members
can render exporters more competitive. Do these arguments apply to CUs?
An often-stated objective of most customs unions
among developing countries is to promote a harmonized
reduction in internal and external trade barriers in order
to better integrate the region into the multilateral trading
system. There are, however, arguments that seem to suggest that CUs create pressures for more protectionism.
Like other integration initiatives, CUs permit member
countries to combine their market size and thereby increase
their market power. Since trade policy is set jointly, this
measure could strengthen their incentive to adopt high
CETs in order to improve their terms of trade. That is,
they can reduce global demand for an imported product,
and thereby decrease the import price, by charging higher
tariffs. The larger the size of the union, the stronger this
proprotectionist effect will be.
Furthermore, if CU members negotiate effectively as a
bloc, they can pool their negotiating power and enhance it
against the rest of the world, thus affecting the outcome of
negotiations. Given the mercantilist nature of trade negotiations, increased negotiating power is likely to lead to a
more protectionist outcome (in exchange for better market
access). It could also be argued that nonmembers will act in
a more conciliatory way when negotiating with a (single,
large) customs union than with separate FTA members, and
the result will be smaller requests for concessions.
The internal process of decision making within the CU
could also place upward pressure on tariffs. The joint, consensual determination of the external tariffs may provide
incentives to agree on higher CETs, since these imply
higher preference margins and benefit partners' firms.
(Protection is afforded to all producers in all CU member
countries.) CU members will internalize this fact and will
choose a higher external tariff (Freund and Ornelas 2010).
Accordingly, one can think of a situation in which each
CU member feels strongly about protecting a particular
sector but would like lower tariffs on the other sectors. As Winters (1996) argues, this may create a prisoner's-dilemma
outcome under which the CET would provide high protection in all sectors, even though each country would be better
off with low protection in all sectors.
The establishment of a CU also changes the power of
lobbies, but it is not clear whether the result will be
stronger or weaker demand for protection. It is possible
that lobbying pressure within a CU may be diluted, compared with national lobbying for protection within an
FTA. As Winters (1996) suggests, it is more costly to lobby
for a tariff increase in a CU than in an individual FTA
member country because there may be more opposition to
overcome or more representatives to influence. Moreover,
the returns to lobbying activities are less under a CU, given
that an extra 1 percent tariff protection becomes available
to all members. Panagariya and Findlay (1996) provide a
formal treatment of the argument that a customs union is
a more effective instrument for diluting the power of
interest groups than is an FTA. The high cost and low
returns of lobbying under a CU could lead to a free-rider
problem in lobbying, and all lobbying could end up taking
place in one country. The author finds that such a process
would yield a lower (common) external tariff under a CU
than under an FTA. The larger the size of the customs
union, the lower the resulting (lobbied) level of common
external tariff would be.
The argument could, of course, cut in the other direction. In some sectors, lobbyists in different member
countries may be able to overcome the free-rider problem, pool their resources, and cooperate. This is likely to
happen in sectors in which they produce relatively similar
goods (say, in agriculture) and where there is little intrabloc trade flow. In this case, the national lobbies would be
able to organize themselves into a regional lobby, and the
resulting common external tariff would be higher in a CU
relative to what would prevail in the individual markets
under an FTA.
The degree of "permanence" of the policy outcomes will
also affect the incentives for, and the amount of, lobbying.
An FTA does not require member countries to immediately
adjust their external tariffs, and it preserves discretion for a
country to adjust its trade policy in the future. By contrast,
a CU requires both tariff adjustments and a relatively
longer-term commitment to the trade policy jointly agreed
on by the CU members – the CET. It is therefore likely that
lobbying for protection would be stronger during the
negotiation and establishment of a CU than in the case of
an FTA. Also, the difficulties in renegotiating or readjusting
the CET could lead to the emergence of less transparent
nontariff barriers that would be implemented at the
national (instead of the regional) level.
Overall, whether opting for a CU leads to higher external
tariffs remains an open question. A number of arguments
seem to suggest that CUs may provide more protectionist
pressures than FTAs. This, however, remains an empirical
question to which the existing literature has not been able to
provide an unequivocal answer.
For most CUs among developing economies, the potential
for losses of tariff revenues constitutes an important negotiation issue. These losses may result from the liberalization
of intraunion tariffs, from the adoption of the common
tariff schedule, or from changes in trade patterns. Given
the significance of tariff revenue for most developing
countries, at least two issues need to be addressed when
establishing a customs union: (a) Who has a claim on the
collected customs duties? (b) Where and how should those
duties be collected?
The use or allocation of the collected duties is an important consideration. Should the customs revenues collected
be treated as community property, or as income accruing
to each member state? Generally, it is necessary to establish
a regional, supranational institution or a secretariat to
ensure smooth operations of the union. Although such an
institution could be funded through direct contributions
from members – for example, WAEMU provides for an
additional tax of 1 percent on imports – treating customs
revenues as the collective property of the union may be a
more useful financing mechanism. In some cases, such as
the EU, the union may decide to allocate (a fraction of)
these revenues to a joint fund to finance regional development initiatives or to provide support to poorer CU members. Of course, pooling customs revenues necessitates a
high level of coordinating capacity and a certain degree of
trust among members. This arrangement seems more
likely to be sustainable when tariff revenues do not constitute an important part of government revenue for individual members – as is the case in the EU, but usually not for
developing economies.
In other cases, CUs treat customs revenues as the
property of individual members. Collected duties are
allocated either according to the final destination or in
line with an agreed sharing formula. Such a formula
could provide for a simple reallocation based on negotiated and fixed shares, or it could involve a more complex
range of economic and demographic variables. SACU,
for instance, has a fairly complicated revenue-sharing system in which the share accruing to each member is
calculated from three basic components: a customs pool,
an excise pool, and a development component. The customs pool is allocated according to each country's share
of total intra-SACU trade, including reexports. The excise
component is allocated on the basis of gross domestic
product (GDP). The development component (fixed at
15 percent of the total excise pool) is distributed to all
SACU members according to each country's per capita
GDP; that is, countries with lower per capita income will
receive more.
Most existing customs unions allocate revenues
according to the final-destination principle. This method,
although apparently simple in theory, requires a mechanism for identifying the final destination of each shipment
entering the union; the destination country would then
claim the appropriate duty amount. One way to handle
this procedure is to keep the imported shipment in
bonded facilities until it reaches the country of ultimate
consumption. This may work for whole shipments of final
goods that are entirely consumed in the destination country, but it may not be the appropriate mechanism for an
imported shipment that undergoes transformation in an
intermediate country before reaching its final destination.
Indeed, incentives could emerge for some members to
collect revenues on imports that are then wholly transshipped or minimally "transformed" or "repackaged"
before being exported duty-free elsewhere in the CU. In
such cases, burdensome internal border controls, guarantee mechanisms, or even some rules of origin are needed
within the CU to determine what fraction of the collected
duties should go to which member. This could be an
important issue for small landlocked economies that rely
on their larger coastal neighbors for transit and that could
lose revenues as a result of leakages or fraud. When trade
flows are sufficiently symmetrical, a member's losses could
be offset by the gains it realizes when goods imported into
its territory (for which it collects the tariff) are consumed
in a neighbor's.
At what point should customs duties be collected – at the
initial port of entry into the CU or at the final import
destination? Collecting import duties at the first port of
entry into the CU (say, in the coastal member with the
more developed port and transit facilities) could be one
way of ensuring freer movement of goods within the CU
and minimizing intra-CU border controls. Indeed, if all
trade taxes were collected at the point of first entry and
administered or distributed centrally, member countries would not need to monitor the passage across their borders
of goods originating outside the CU for duty collection
purposes. This method would greatly enhance efficiency
by reducing transaction costs at internal border posts, but
it requires the existence of the appropriate institutional
capacity to administer the revenues and, most important,
a high level of trust among members. Both of these measures tend to be harder to achieve as the number and
diversity of member states increase. The mechanism is
more likely to be sustainable if customs duties are deemed
to be community property of the CU and are used for collectively determined community purposes, or if members
can devise a mechanism for identifying imports according to their final destinations. A potential issue is the
possibility of some diversion in revenue collections (and
even economic activity) away from landlocked and less
developed countries and toward the more developed
trading hubs in the region.
Alternatively, customs duties could be collected at
the final destination or the final consumption point. Although conceptually straightforward, this type of agreement can be complex to implement and can be very costly.
In fact, to be workable, it requires that significant border
controls remain or that goods be shipped in some sort of
transit and bonding facility all the way to the final destination, where duties would be collected. Not only would
the logistical costs of running such facilities be substantial,
but they would also tend to diminish some of the expected
gains from establishing a CU. For instance, they could discourage the establishment of regional value chains or processing chains (using imported inputs) or the generation
of retail and wholesale services in intermediate locations
between the initial port of entry and the final destination.
It is clear from the foregoing discussion that the collection
and allocation of customs revenue in a customs union setting
are not only technical issues, but also (perhaps more important) a question of trust. Good technical coordination and
enforcement generally promote trust among CU members.
Conversely, lack of trust would require more stringent and
cumbersome controls on intrabloc transit and stricter application of the agreed disposition of revenue. This is clearly an
area in which harmonization of border management (customs procedures), cooperation, modernization, and capacity
building could be very useful.
The conceptual discussions in this chapter demonstrate
that CUs generally require a much greater degree of policy
coordination among members than do FTAs. This is because they require member countries to agree to a
common external tariff and to set up institutional mechanisms to collect and distribute the tariff revenue. When a
country joins a customs union, it agrees to relinquish
some of its national sovereignty with respect to the formulation and implementation of trade policy. The fact that a
country is willing to surrender such autonomy over trade
policy suggests that it considers this loss to be more than
offset by the economic benefits of securing access to a
larger and more harmonized regional market and of
enhancing the depth and effectiveness of the ongoing
regional integration. The loss of autonomy may also be
acceptable to members because in most cases, CUs are
driven by objectives that go beyond trade, such as economic and monetary unions or even political integration,
and that require supranational institutions.
Ceding the control of some aspects of national trade
policy may yield economic benefits, to the extent that it
shelters the trade policy–making process from the influence of special interests, at least at the national level. Committing to a regionally agreed trade policy regime can
serve as an effective lock-in mechanism for trade reform
efforts and can send a strong signal to investors regarding
the predictability of the policy environment. In some
cases, it may be more practical for a country to delegate
the conduct of trade policy to another (larger) CU member or to a supranational agency. In others, a larger member country can impose its own trade policy or tariff
structure on that of the union. In this case, there may be
grounds for establishing a regional mechanism, such as a
development fund, to compensate other member countries for adopting a tariff structure that is not inherently in
their own economic interests.
It should be noted that the loss of autonomy implied
by a CU also covers certain aspects of national trade policies, going beyond external tariffs. For instance, whereas
FTA members retain full flexibility with regard to future
PTA partners, CU members may be limited in their individual choices for future partners Indeed, membership in
a CU, at least in principle, prevents an individual member
from acting individually, since any agreement with a third
party or any change to the CET needs to be decided by the
CU as a whole. It can be argued that CUs could help prevent the emergence of a hub-and-spokes trading pattern.
In a world of criss-crossing and overlapping trade
agreements, the issue of the loss of autonomy can severely
constrain members of CUs in using trade agreements as an
effective commercial instrument – at least in theory. In the
current wave of regionalism, in which flexibility and speed are valued, membership in a CU, if played by the rules,
could constitute a straitjacket for some countries.
In reality, of course, there are numerous cases in which
a CU member alone negotiates an FTA with a third party.
Examples of such a situation include the FTAs between the
EU and South Africa (a member of SACU) and between
the United States and Bahrain (a member of the GCC).
Similarly, Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, and the
República Bolivariana de Venezuela form the Andean Pact
(a CU), while Colombia and the República Bolivariana de
Venezuela have joined with Mexico to make up the Group
of Three, an FTA. In some instances, one CU may overlap
another. For example, Lesotho, Namibia, and Swaziland
belong to COMESA while also belonging to SACU, and
Tanzania is a member of both the SADC and the EAC.
Multiple and overlapping memberships in regional trade
agreements can create difficulties because different groups
can have conflicting operational or liberalization modalities, and so member countries will have to make different,
incompatible commitments. This not only could render
CUs less effective but could also confuse traders (and even
customs officers) as to which commitments or tariff
schedules apply to a particular shipment. Unnecessary
transaction costs will be created because traders are
obliged to find their way around a number of trade
regimes with different tariff schedules, different rules of
origin, and different procedures.