Demand, Supply, and Equilibrium
Site: | Saylor Academy |
Course: | BUS606: Operations and Supply Chain Management |
Book: | Demand, Supply, and Equilibrium |
Printed by: | Guest user |
Date: | Thursday, 3 April 2025, 10:57 PM |
Description
Read this chapter. Pay particular attention to the section on the relationship between gas prices and community natural resource consumption.
Demand, Supply, and Equilibrium in Markets for Goods and Services
Learning Objectives
By the end of this section, you will be able to:
- Explain demand, quantity demanded, and the law of demand
- Identify a demand curve and a supply curve
- Explain supply, quantity supply, and the law of supply
- Explain equilibrium, equilibrium price, and equilibrium quantity
First let's first focus on what economists mean by demand, what they mean by supply, and then how demand and supply interact in a market.
Demand for Goods and Services
Economists use the term demand to refer to the amount of some good or service consumers are willing and able to purchase at each price. Demand is based on needs and wants – a consumer may be able to differentiate between a need and a want, but from an economist's perspective they are the same thing. Demand is also based on ability to pay. If you cannot pay for it, you have no effective demand.
What a buyer pays for a unit of the specific good or service is called price. The total number of units purchased at that price is called the quantity demanded.
A rise in price of a good or service almost always decreases the
quantity demanded of that good or service. Conversely, a fall in price
will increase the quantity demanded. When the price of a gallon of
gasoline goes up, for example, people look for ways to reduce their
consumption by combining several errands, commuting by carpool or mass
transit, or taking weekend or vacation trips closer to home. Economists
call this inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded the law of demand. The law of demand assumes that all other variables that affect demand (to be explained in the next module) are held constant.
An example from the market for gasoline can be shown in the form of a
table or a graph. A table that shows the quantity demanded at each
price, such as Table 1, is called a demand schedule.
Price in this case is measured in dollars per gallon of gasoline. The
quantity demanded is measured in millions of gallons over some time
period (for example, per day or per year) and over some geographic area
(like a state or a country). A demand curve shows the relationship between price and quantity demanded on a graph like Figure 1,
with quantity on the horizontal axis and the price per gallon on the
vertical axis. (Note that this is an exception to the normal rule in
mathematics that the independent variable (x) goes on the horizontal
axis and the dependent variable (y) goes on the vertical. Economics is
not math.)
The demand schedule shown by Table 1 and the demand curve shown by the graph in Figure 1 are two ways of describing the same relationship between price and quantity demanded.
Figure 1. A Demand Curve for Gasoline. The demand
schedule shows that as price rises, quantity demanded decreases, and
vice versa. These points are then graphed, and the line connecting them
is the demand curve (D). The downward slope of the demand curve again
illustrates the law of demand – the inverse relationship between prices
and quantity demanded.
Price (per gallon) | Quantity Demanded (millions of gallons) |
---|---|
$1.00 | 800 |
$1.20 | 700 |
$1.40 | 600 |
$1.60 | 550 |
$1.80 | 500 |
$2.00 | 460 |
$2.20 | 420 |
Table 1. Price and Quantity Demanded of Gasoline |
Demand curves will appear somewhat different for each product. They may appear relatively steep or flat, or they may be straight or curved. Nearly all demand curves share the fundamental similarity that they slope down from left to right. So demand curves embody the law of demand: As the price increases, the quantity demanded decreases, and conversely, as the price decreases, the quantity demanded increases.
In economic terminology, demand is not the same as quantity demanded. When economists talk about demand, they mean the relationship between a range of prices and the quantities demanded at those prices, as illustrated by a demand curve or a demand schedule. When economists talk about quantity demanded, they mean only a certain point on the demand curve, or one quantity on the demand schedule. In short, demand refers to the curve and quantity demanded refers to the (specific) point on the curve.
Supply of Goods and Services
When economists talk about supply, they mean the amount of some good or service a producer is willing to supply at each price. Price is what the producer receives for selling one unit of a good or service. A rise in price almost always leads to an increase in the quantity supplied of that good or service, while a fall in price will decrease the quantity supplied. When the price of gasoline rises, for example, it encourages profit-seeking firms to take several actions: expand exploration for oil reserves; drill for more oil; invest in more pipelines and oil tankers to bring the oil to plants where it can be refined into gasoline; build new oil refineries; purchase additional pipelines and trucks to ship the gasoline to gas stations; and open more gas stations or keep existing gas stations open longer hours. Economists call this positive relationship between price and quantity supplied – that a higher price leads to a higher quantity supplied and a lower price leads to a lower quantity supplied – the law of supply. The law of supply assumes that all other variables that affect supply (to be explained in the next module) are held constant.
Is supply the same as quantity supplied?
In economic terminology, supply is not the same as quantity supplied. When economists refer to supply, they mean the relationship between a range of prices and the quantities supplied at those prices, a relationship that can be illustrated with a supply curve or a supply schedule. When economists refer to quantity supplied, they mean only a certain point on the supply curve, or one quantity on the supply schedule. In short, supply refers to the curve and quantity supplied refers to the (specific) point on the curve.
Figure 2. A Supply Curve for Gasoline. The supply
schedule is the table that shows quantity supplied of gasoline at each
price. As price rises, quantity supplied also increases, and vice versa.
The supply curve (S) is created by graphing the points from the supply
schedule and then connecting them. The upward slope of the supply curve
illustrates the law of supply – that a higher price leads to a higher
quantity supplied, and vice versa.
Price (per gallon) | Quantity Supplied (millions of gallons) |
---|---|
$1.00 | 500 |
$1.20 | 550 |
$1.40 | 600 |
$1.60 | 640 |
$1.80 | 680 |
$2.00 | 700 |
$2.20 | 720 |
Table 2. Price and Supply of Gasoline |
The shape of supply curves will vary somewhat according to the product:
steeper, flatter, straighter, or curved. Nearly all supply curves,
however, share a basic similarity: they slope up from left to right and
illustrate the law of supply: as the price rises, say, from $1.00 per
gallon to $2.20 per gallon, the quantity supplied increases from 500
gallons to 720 gallons. Conversely, as the price falls, the quantity
supplied decreases.
Equilibrium – Where Demand and Supply Intersect
Because the graphs for demand and supply curves both have price on the vertical axis and quantity on the horizontal axis, the demand curve and supply curve for a particular good or service can appear on the same graph. Together, demand and supply determine the price and the quantity that will be bought and sold in a market.
Figure 3 illustrates the interaction of demand and supply in the market for gasoline. The demand curve (D) is identical to Figure 1. The supply curve (S) is identical to Figure 2. Table 3 contains the same information in tabular form.
Figure 3. Demand and Supply for Gasoline. The demand
curve (D) and the supply curve (S) intersect at the equilibrium point E,
with a price of $1.40 and a quantity of 600. The equilibrium is the
only price where quantity demanded is equal to quantity supplied. At a
price above equilibrium like $1.80, quantity supplied exceeds the
quantity demanded, so there is excess supply. At a price below
equilibrium such as $1.20, quantity demanded exceeds quantity supplied,
so there is excess demand.
Price (per gallon) | Quantity demanded (millions of gallons) | Quantity supplied (millions of gallons) |
---|---|---|
$1.00 | 800 | 500 |
$1.20 | 700 | 550 |
$1.40 | 600 | 600 |
$1.60 | 550 | 640 |
$1.80 | 500 | 680 |
$2.00 | 460 | 700 |
$2.20 | 420 | 720 |
Table 3. Price, Quantity Demanded, and Quantity Supplied |
Remember this: When two lines on a diagram cross, this intersection
usually means something. The point where the supply curve (S) and the
demand curve (D) cross, designated by point E in Figure 3, is called the equilibrium. The equilibrium price
is the only price where the plans of consumers and the plans of
producers agree – that is, where the amount of the product consumers want
to buy (quantity demanded) is equal to the amount producers want to sell
(quantity supplied). This common quantity is called the equilibrium quantity.
At any other price, the quantity demanded does not equal the quantity
supplied, so the market is not in equilibrium at that price.
In Figure 3,
the equilibrium price is $1.40 per gallon of gasoline and the
equilibrium quantity is 600 million gallons. If you had only the demand
and supply schedules, and not the graph, you could find the equilibrium
by looking for the price level on the tables where the quantity demanded
and the quantity supplied are equal.
The word "equilibrium" means "balance". If a market is at its
equilibrium price and quantity, then it has no reason to move away from
that point. However, if a market is not at equilibrium, then economic
pressures arise to move the market toward the equilibrium price and the
equilibrium quantity.
Imagine, for example, that the price of a gallon of gasoline was above
the equilibrium price – that is, instead of $1.40 per gallon, the price is
$1.80 per gallon. This above-equilibrium price is illustrated by the
dashed horizontal line at the price of $1.80 in Figure 3.
At this higher price, the quantity demanded drops from 600 to 500. This
decline in quantity reflects how consumers react to the higher price by
finding ways to use less gasoline.
Moreover, at this higher price of $1.80, the quantity of gasoline
supplied rises from the 600 to 680, as the higher price makes it more
profitable for gasoline producers to expand their output. Now, consider
how quantity demanded and quantity supplied are related at this
above-equilibrium price. Quantity demanded has fallen to 500 gallons,
while quantity supplied has risen to 680 gallons. In fact, at any
above-equilibrium price, the quantity supplied exceeds the quantity
demanded. We call this an excess supply or a surplus.
With a surplus, gasoline accumulates at gas stations, in tanker trucks,
in pipelines, and at oil refineries. This accumulation puts pressure on
gasoline sellers. If a surplus remains unsold, those firms involved in
making and selling gasoline are not receiving enough cash to pay their
workers and to cover their expenses. In this situation, some producers
and sellers will want to cut prices, because it is better to sell at a
lower price than not to sell at all. Once some sellers start cutting
prices, others will follow to avoid losing sales. These price reductions
in turn will stimulate a higher quantity demanded. So, if the price is
above the equilibrium level, incentives built into the structure of
demand and supply will create pressures for the price to fall toward the
equilibrium.
Now suppose that the price is below its equilibrium level at $1.20 per gallon, as the dashed horizontal line at this price in Figure 3
shows. At this lower price, the quantity demanded increases from 600 to
700 as drivers take longer trips, spend more minutes warming up the car
in the driveway in wintertime, stop sharing rides to work, and buy
larger cars that get fewer miles to the gallon. However, the
below-equilibrium price reduces gasoline producers' incentives to
produce and sell gasoline, and the quantity supplied falls from 600 to
550.
When the price is below equilibrium, there is excess demand, or a shortage – that
is, at the given price the quantity demanded, which has been stimulated
by the lower price, now exceeds the quantity supplied, which had been
depressed by the lower price. In this situation, eager gasoline buyers
mob the gas stations, only to find many stations running short of fuel.
Oil companies and gas stations recognize that they have an opportunity
to make higher profits by selling what gasoline they have at a higher
price. As a result, the price rises toward the equilibrium level. Read Demand, Supply, and Efficiency for more discussion on the importance of the demand and supply model.
Key Concepts and Summary
A demand schedule is a table that shows the quantity demanded at different prices in the market. A demand curve shows the relationship between quantity demanded and price in a given market on a graph. The law of demand states that a higher price typically leads to a lower quantity demanded.
A supply schedule is a table that shows the quantity supplied at
different prices in the market. A supply curve shows the relationship
between quantity supplied and price on a graph. The law of supply says
that a higher price typically leads to a higher quantity supplied.
The equilibrium price and equilibrium quantity occur where the supply
and demand curves cross. The equilibrium occurs where the quantity
demanded is equal to the quantity supplied. If the price is below the
equilibrium level, then the quantity demanded will exceed the quantity
supplied. Excess demand or a shortage will exist. If the price is above
the equilibrium level, then the quantity supplied will exceed the
quantity demanded. Excess supply or a surplus will exist. In either
case, economic pressures will push the price toward the equilibrium
level.
Source: Rice University, https://opentextbc.ca/principlesofeconomics/chapter/3-1-demand-supply-and-equilibrium-in-markets-for-goods-and-services/
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 License.
Shifts in Demand and Supply for Goods and Services
Learning Objectives
By the end of this section, you will be able to:
- Identify factors that affect demand
- Graph demand curves and demand shifts
- Identify factors that affect supply
- Graph supply curves and supply shifts
The previous module explored how price affects the quantity demanded and the quantity supplied. The result was the demand curve and the supply curve. Price, however, is not the only thing that influences demand. Nor is it the only thing that influences supply. For example, how is demand for vegetarian food affected if, say, health concerns cause more consumers to avoid eating meat? Or how is the supply of diamonds affected if diamond producers discover several new diamond mines? What are the major factors, in addition to the price, that influence demand or supply?
What Factors Affect Demand?
We defined demand as the amount of some product a consumer is willing and able to purchase at each price. That suggests at least two factors in addition to price that affect demand. Willingness to purchase suggests a desire, based on what economists call tastes and preferences. If you neither need nor want something, you will not buy it. Ability to purchase suggests that income is important. Professors are usually able to afford better housing and transportation than students, because they have more income. Prices of related goods can affect demand also. If you need a new car, the price of a Honda may affect your demand for a Ford. Finally, the size or composition of the population can affect demand. The more children a family has, the greater their demand for clothing. The more driving-age children a family has, the greater their demand for car insurance, and the less for diapers and baby formula.
These factors matter both for demand by an individual and demand by the market as a whole. Exactly how do these various factors affect demand, and how do we show the effects graphically? To answer those questions, we need the ceteris paribus assumption.
The Ceteris Paribus Assumption
A demand curve or a supply curve is a relationship between two, and only two, variables: quantity on the horizontal axis and price on the vertical axis. The assumption behind a demand curve or a supply curve is that no relevant economic factors, other than the product's price, are changing. Economists call this assumption ceteris paribus, a Latin phrase meaning "other things being equal". Any given demand or supply curve is based on the ceteris paribus assumption that all else is held equal. A demand curve or a supply curve is a relationship between two, and only two, variables when all other variables are kept constant. If all else is not held equal, then the laws of supply and demand will not necessarily hold, as the following Clear It Up feature shows.
When does ceteris paribus apply?
For example, we can say that an increase in the price reduces the amount consumers will buy (assuming income, and anything else that affects demand, is unchanged). Additionally, a decrease in income reduces the amount consumers can afford to buy (assuming price, and anything else that affects demand, is unchanged). This is what the ceteris paribus assumption really means. In this particular case, after we analyze each factor separately, we can combine the results. The amount consumers buy falls for two reasons: first because of the higher price and second because of the lower income.
How Does Income Affect Demand?
Let's use income as an example of how factors other than price affect demand. Figure 1 shows the initial demand for automobiles as D0. At point Q, for example, if the price is $20,000 per car, the quantity of cars demanded is 18 million. D0 also shows how the quantity of cars demanded would change as a result of a higher or lower price. For example, if the price of a car rose to $22,000, the quantity demanded would decrease to 17 million, at point R.
The original demand curve D0, like every demand curve, is based on the ceteris paribus assumption that no other economically relevant factors change. Now imagine that the economy expands in a way that raises the incomes of many people, making cars more affordable. How will this affect demand? How can we show this graphically?
Return to Figure 1. The price of cars is still $20,000, but with higher incomes, the quantity demanded has now increased to 20 million cars, shown at point S. As a result of the higher income levels, the demand curve shifts to the right to the new demand curve D1, indicating an increase in demand. Table 4 shows clearly that this increased demand would occur at every price, not just the original one.

Figure 1. Shifts in Demand: A Car Example. Increased
demand means that at every given price, the quantity demanded is higher,
so that the demand curve shifts to the right from D0 to D1.
Decreased demand means that at every given price, the quantity demanded
is lower, so that the demand curve shifts to the left from D0 to D2.
Price | Decrease to D2 | Original Quantity Demanded D0 | Increase to D1 |
---|---|---|---|
$16,000 | 17.6 million | 22.0 million | 24.0 million |
$18,000 | 16.0 million | 20.0 million | 22.0 million |
$20,000 | 14.4 million | 18.0 million | 20.0 million |
$22,000 | 13.6 million | 17.0 million | 19.0 million |
$24,000 | 13.2 million | 16.5 million | 18.5 million |
$26,000 | 12.8 million | 16.0 million | 18.0 million |
Table 4. Price and Demand Shifts: A Car Example |
Now, imagine that the economy slows down so that many people lose their
jobs or work fewer hours, reducing their incomes. In this case, the
decrease in income would lead to a lower quantity of cars demanded at
every given price, and the original demand curve D0 would shift left to D2. The shift from D0 to D2
represents such a decrease in demand: At any given price level, the
quantity demanded is now lower. In this example, a price of $20,000
means 18 million cars sold along the original demand curve, but only
14.4 million sold after demand fell.
When a demand curve shifts, it does not mean that the quantity demanded
by every individual buyer changes by the same amount. In this example,
not everyone would have higher or lower income and not everyone would
buy or not buy an additional car. Instead, a shift in a demand curve
captures an pattern for the market as a whole.
In the previous section, we argued that higher income causes greater
demand at every price. This is true for most goods and services. For
some – luxury cars, vacations in Europe, and fine jewelry – the effect of a
rise in income can be especially pronounced. A product whose demand
rises when income rises, and vice versa, is called a normal good.
A few exceptions to this pattern do exist. As incomes rise, many people
will buy fewer generic brand groceries and more name brand groceries.
They are less likely to buy used cars and more likely to buy new cars.
They will be less likely to rent an apartment and more likely to own a
home, and so on. A product whose demand falls when income rises, and
vice versa, is called an inferior good. In other words, when income increases, the demand curve shifts to the left.
Other Factors That Shift Demand Curves
Income is not the only factor that causes a shift in demand. Other things that change demand include tastes and preferences, the composition or size of the population, the prices of related goods, and even expectations. A change in any one of the underlying factors that determine what quantity people are willing to buy at a given price will cause a shift in demand. Graphically, the new demand curve lies either to the right (an increase) or to the left (a decrease) of the original demand curve. Let's look at these factors.
Changing Tastes or Preferences
From 1980 to 2014, the per-person consumption of chicken by Americans
rose from 48 pounds per year to 85 pounds per year, and consumption of
beef fell from 77 pounds per year to 54 pounds per year, according to
the U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA). Changes like these are
largely due to movements in taste, which change the quantity of a good
demanded at every price: that is, they shift the demand curve for that
good, rightward for chicken and leftward for beef.
Changes in the Composition of the Population
The proportion of elderly citizens in the United States population is
rising. It rose from 9.8% in 1970 to 12.6% in 2000, and will be a
projected (by the U.S. Census Bureau)
20% of the population by 2030. A society with relatively more children,
like the United States in the 1960s, will have greater demand for goods
and services like tricycles and day care facilities. A society with
relatively more elderly persons, as the United States is projected to
have by 2030, has a higher demand for nursing homes and hearing aids.
Similarly, changes in the size of the population can affect the demand
for housing and many other goods. Each of these changes in demand will
be shown as a shift in the demand curve.
The demand for a product can also be affected by changes in the prices of related goods such as substitutes or complements. A substitute
is a good or service that can be used in place of another good or
service. As electronic books, like this one, become more available, you
would expect to see a decrease in demand for traditional printed books. A
lower price for a substitute decreases demand for the other product.
For example, in recent years as the price of tablet computers has
fallen, the quantity demanded has increased (because of the law of
demand). Since people are purchasing tablets, there has been a decrease
in demand for laptops, which can be shown graphically as a leftward
shift in the demand curve for laptops. A higher price for a substitute
good has the reverse effect.
Other goods are complements for each other, meaning that the goods are often used together, because consumption of one good tends to enhance consumption of the other. Examples include breakfast cereal and milk; notebooks and pens or pencils, golf balls and golf clubs; gasoline and sport utility vehicles; and the five-way combination of bacon, lettuce, tomato, mayonnaise, and bread. If the price of golf clubs rises, since the quantity demanded of golf clubs falls (because of the law of demand), demand for a complement good like golf balls decreases, too. Similarly, a higher price for skis would shift the demand curve for a complement good like ski resort trips to the left, while a lower price for a complement has the reverse effect.
Changes in Expectations about Future Prices or Other Factors that Affect Demand
While it is clear that the price of a good affects the quantity demanded, it is also true that expectations about the future price (or expectations about tastes and preferences, income, and so on) can affect demand. For example, if people hear that a hurricane is coming, they may rush to the store to buy flashlight batteries and bottled water. If people learn that the price of a good like coffee is likely to rise in the future, they may head for the store to stock up on coffee now. These changes in demand are shown as shifts in the curve. Therefore, a shift in demand happens when a change in some economic factor (other than price) causes a different quantity to be demanded at every price. The following Work It Out feature shows how this happens.
Shift in DemandA shift in demand means that at any price (and at every price), the quantity demanded will be different than it was before. Following is an example of a shift in demand due to an income increase.
Step 1. Draw the graph of a demand curve for a normal good like pizza. Pick a price (like P0). Identify the corresponding Q0. An example is shown in Figure 2.

Step 2. Suppose income increases. As a result of the change, are
consumers going to buy more or less pizza? The answer is more. Draw a
dotted horizontal line from the chosen price, through the original
quantity demanded, to the new point with the new Q1. Draw a dotted vertical line down to the horizontal axis and label the new Q1. An example is provided in Figure 3.
Figure 3. Demand Curve with Income Increase. With an
increase in income, consumers will purchase larger quantities, pushing
demand to the right.
Figure 4. Demand Curve Shifted Right. With an increase
in income, consumers will purchase larger quantities, pushing demand to
the right, and causing the demand curve to shift right.
Summing Up Factors That Change Demand
Six factors that can shift demand curves are summarized in Figure 5. The direction of the arrows indicates whether the demand curve shifts represent an increase in demand or a decrease in demand. Notice that a change in the price of the good or service itself is not listed among the factors that can shift a demand curve. A change in the price of a good or service causes a movement along a specific demand curve, and it typically leads to some change in the quantity demanded, but it does not shift the demand curve.
Figure 5. Factors That Shift Demand Curves. (a) A list of factors that can cause an increase in demand from D0 to D1. (b) The same factors, if their direction is reversed, can cause a decrease in demand from D0 to D1.
When a demand curve shifts, it will then intersect with a given supply
curve at a different equilibrium price and quantity. We are, however,
getting ahead of our story. Before discussing how changes in demand can
affect equilibrium price and quantity, we first need to discuss shifts
in supply curves.
How Production Costs Affect Supply
A supply curve shows how quantity supplied will change as the price rises and falls, assuming ceteris paribus so that no other economically relevant factors are changing. If other factors relevant to supply do change, then the entire supply curve will shift. Just as a shift in demand is represented by a change in the quantity demanded at every price, a shift in supply means a change in the quantity supplied at every price.
In thinking about the factors that affect supply, remember what motivates firms: profits, which are the difference between revenues and costs. Goods and services are produced using combinations of labor, materials, and machinery, or what we call inputs or factors of production. If a firm faces lower costs of production, while the prices for the good or service the firm produces remain unchanged, a firm's profits go up. When a firm's profits increase, it is more motivated to produce output, since the more it produces the more profit it will earn. So, when costs of production fall, a firm will tend to supply a larger quantity at any given price for its output. This can be shown by the supply curve shifting to the right.
Take, for example, a messenger company that delivers packages around a city. The company may find that buying gasoline is one of its main costs. If the price of gasoline falls, then the company will find it can deliver messages more cheaply than before. Since lower costs correspond to higher profits, the messenger company may now supply more of its services at any given price. For example, given the lower gasoline prices, the company can now serve a greater area, and increase its supply.
Conversely, if a firm faces higher costs of production, then it will earn lower profits at any given selling price for its products. As a result, a higher cost of production typically causes a firm to supply a smaller quantity at any given price. In this case, the supply curve shifts to the left.
Consider the supply for cars, shown by curve S0 in Figure 6. Point J indicates that if the price is $20,000, the quantity supplied will be 18 million cars. If the price rises to $22,000 per car, ceteris paribus, the quantity supplied will rise to 20 million cars, as point K on the S0 curve shows. The same information can be shown in table form, as in Table 5.

Figure 6. Shifts in Supply: A Car Example. Decreased
supply means that at every given price, the quantity supplied is lower,
so that the supply curve shifts to the left, from S0 to S1.
Increased supply means that at every given price, the quantity supplied
is higher, so that the supply curve shifts to the right, from S0 to S2.
Price | Decrease to S1 | Original Quantity Supplied S0 | Increase to S2 |
---|---|---|---|
$16,000 | 10.5 million | 12.0 million | 13.2 million |
$18,000 | 13.5 million | 15.0 million | 16.5 million |
$20,000 | 16.5 million | 18.0 million | 19.8 million |
$22,000 | 18.5 million | 20.0 million | 22.0 million |
$24,000 | 19.5 million | 21.0 million | 23.1 million |
$26,000 | 20.5 million | 22.0 million | 24.2 million |
Table 5. Price and Shifts in Supply: A Car Example |
Now, imagine that the price of steel, an important ingredient in
manufacturing cars, rises, so that producing a car has become more
expensive. At any given price for selling cars, car manufacturers will
react by supplying a lower quantity. This can be shown graphically as a
leftward shift of supply, from S0 to S1, which
indicates that at any given price, the quantity supplied decreases. In
this example, at a price of $20,000, the quantity supplied decreases
from 18 million on the original supply curve (S0) to 16.5 million on the supply curve S1, which is labeled as point L.
Conversely, if the price of steel decreases, producing a car becomes
less expensive. At any given price for selling cars, car manufacturers
can now expect to earn higher profits, so they will supply a higher
quantity. The shift of supply to the right, from S0 to S2,
means that at all prices, the quantity supplied has increased. In this
example, at a price of $20,000, the quantity supplied increases from 18
million on the original supply curve (S0) to 19.8 million on the supply curve S2, which is labeled M.
Other Factors That Affect Supply
In the example above, we saw that changes in the prices of inputs in the production process will affect the cost of production and thus the supply. Several other things affect the cost of production, too, such as changes in weather or other natural conditions, new technologies for production, and some government policies.
The cost of production for many agricultural products will be affected by changes in natural conditions. For example, in 2014 the Manchurian Plain in Northeastern China, which produces most of the country's wheat, corn, and soybeans, experienced its most severe drought in 50 years. A drought decreases the supply of agricultural products, which means that at any given price, a lower quantity will be supplied; conversely, especially good weather would shift the supply curve to the right.
When a firm discovers a new technology that allows the firm to produce at a lower cost, the supply curve will shift to the right, as well. For instance, in the 1960s a major scientific effort nicknamed the Green Revolution focused on breeding improved seeds for basic crops like wheat and rice. By the early 1990s, more than two-thirds of the wheat and rice in low-income countries around the world was grown with these Green Revolution seeds – and the harvest was twice as high per acre. A technological improvement that reduces costs of production will shift supply to the right, so that a greater quantity will be produced at any given price.
Government policies can affect the cost of production and the supply curve through taxes, regulations, and subsidies. For example, the U.S. government imposes a tax on alcoholic beverages that collects about $8 billion per year from producers. Taxes are treated as costs by businesses. Higher costs decrease supply for the reasons discussed above. Other examples of policy that can affect cost are the wide array of government regulations that require firms to spend money to provide a cleaner environment or a safer workplace; complying with regulations increases costs.
A government subsidy, on the other hand, is the opposite of a tax. A subsidy occurs when the government pays a firm directly or reduces the firm's taxes if the firm carries out certain actions. From the firm's perspective, taxes or regulations are an additional cost of production that shifts supply to the left, leading the firm to produce a lower quantity at every given price. Government subsidies reduce the cost of production and increase supply at every given price, shifting supply to the right. The following Work It Out feature shows how this shift happens.
Shift in SupplyWe know that a supply curve shows the minimum price a firm will accept to produce a given quantity of output. What happens to the supply curve when the cost of production goes up? Following is an example of a shift in supply due to a production cost increase.
Step 1. Draw a graph of a supply curve for pizza. Pick a quantity (like Q0). If you draw a vertical line up from Q0 to the supply curve, you will see the price the firm chooses. An example is shown in Figure 7.

Figure 7. Supply Curve. The supply curve can be used to show the minimum price a firm will accept to produce a given quantity of output.
Figure 8. Setting Prices. The cost of production and the desired profit equal the price a firm will set for a product.
Figure 9. Increasing Costs Leads to Increasing Price.
Because the cost of production and the desired profit equal the price a
firm will set for a product, if the cost of production increases, the
price for the product will also need to increase.
Figure 10. Supply Curve Shifts. When the cost of production increases, the supply curve shifts upwardly to a new price level.
Summing Up Factors That Change Supply
Changes in the cost of inputs, natural disasters, new technologies, and the impact of government decisions all affect the cost of production. In turn, these factors affect how much firms are willing to supply at any given price.
Figure 11 summarizes factors that change the supply of goods and services. Notice that a change in the price of the product itself is not among the factors that shift the supply curve. Although a change in price of a good or service typically causes a change in quantity supplied or a movement along the supply curve for that specific good or service, it does not cause the supply curve itself to shift.

Figure 11. Factors That Shift Supply Curves. (a) A list of factors that can cause an increase in supply from S0 to S1. (b) The same factors, if their direction is reversed, can cause a decrease in supply from S0 to S1.
Because demand and supply curves appear on a two-dimensional diagram
with only price and quantity on the axes, an unwary visitor to the land
of economics might be fooled into believing that economics is about only
four topics: demand, supply, price, and quantity. However, demand and
supply are really "umbrella" concepts: demand covers all the factors
that affect demand, and supply covers all the factors that affect
supply. Factors other than price that affect demand and supply are
included by using shifts in the demand or the supply curve. In this way,
the two-dimensional demand and supply model becomes a powerful tool for
analyzing a wide range of economic circumstances.
Key Concepts and Summary
Economists often use the ceteris paribus or "other things being equal" assumption: while examining the economic impact of one event, all other factors remain unchanged for the purpose of the analysis. Factors that can shift the demand curve for goods and services, causing a different quantity to be demanded at any given price, include changes in tastes, population, income, prices of substitute or complement goods, and expectations about future conditions and prices. Factors that can shift the supply curve for goods and services, causing a different quantity to be supplied at any given price, include input prices, natural conditions, changes in technology, and government taxes, regulations, or subsidies.
Changes in Equilibrium Price and Quantity: The Four-Step Process
Learning Objectives
By the end of this section, you will be able to:
- Identify equilibrium price and quantity through the four-step process
- Graph equilibrium price and quantity
- Contrast shifts of demand or supply and movements along a demand or supply curve
- Graph demand and supply curves, including equilibrium price and quantity, based on real-world examples
Let's begin this discussion with a single economic event. It might be an event that affects demand, like a change in income, population, tastes, prices of substitutes or complements, or expectations about future prices. It might be an event that affects supply, like a change in natural conditions, input prices, or technology, or government policies that affect production. How does this economic event affect equilibrium price and quantity? We will analyze this question using a four-step process.
Step 1. Draw a demand and supply model before the economic change took place. To establish the model requires four standard pieces of information: The law of demand, which tells us the slope of the demand curve; the law of supply, which gives us the slope of the supply curve; the shift variables for demand; and the shift variables for supply. From this model, find the initial equilibrium values for price and quantity.
Step 2. Decide whether the economic change being analyzed affects demand or supply. In other words, does the event refer to something in the list of demand factors or supply factors?
Step 3. Decide whether the effect on demand or supply causes the curve to shift to the right or to the left, and sketch the new demand or supply curve on the diagram. In other words, does the event increase or decrease the amount consumers want to buy or producers want to sell?
Step 4. Identify the new equilibrium and then compare the original equilibrium price and quantity to the new equilibrium price and quantity.
Let's consider one example that involves a shift in supply and one that involves a shift in demand. Then we will consider an example where both supply and demand shift.
Good Weather for Salmon Fishing
In the summer of 2000, weather conditions were excellent for commercial salmon fishing off the California coast. Heavy rains meant higher than normal levels of water in the rivers, which helps the salmon to breed. Slightly cooler ocean temperatures stimulated the growth of plankton, the microscopic organisms at the bottom of the ocean food chain, providing everything in the ocean with a hearty food supply. The ocean stayed calm during fishing season, so commercial fishing operations did not lose many days to bad weather. How did these climate conditions affect the quantity and price of salmon? Figure 1 illustrates the four-step approach, which is explained below, to work through this problem. Table 7 provides the information to work the problem as well.
Figure 1. Good Weather for Salmon Fishing: The
Four-Step Process. Unusually good weather leads to changes in the price
and quantity of salmon.
Price per Pound | Quantity Supplied in 1999 | Quantity Supplied in 2000 | Quantity Demanded |
---|---|---|---|
$2.00 | 80 | 400 | 840 |
$2.25 | 120 | 480 | 680 |
$2.50 | 160 | 550 | 550 |
$2.75 | 200 | 600 | 450 |
$3.00 | 230 | 640 | 350 |
$3.25 | 250 | 670 | 250 |
$3.50 | 270 | 700 | 200 |
Table 7. Salmon Fishing |
Step 1. Draw a demand and supply model to illustrate the market for salmon in the year before the good weather conditions began. The demand curve D0 and the supply curve S0 show that the original equilibrium price is $3.25 per pound and the original equilibrium quantity is 250,000 fish. (This price per pound is what commercial buyers pay at the fishing docks; what consumers pay at the grocery is higher.)
Step 2. Did the economic event affect supply or demand? Good weather is an example of a natural condition that affects supply.
Step 3. Was the effect on supply an increase or a decrease? Good weather is a change in natural conditions that increases the quantity supplied at any given price. The supply curve shifts to the right, moving from the original supply curve S0 to the new supply curve S1, which is shown in both the table and the figure.
Step 4. Compare the new equilibrium price and quantity to the original equilibrium. At the new equilibrium E1, the equilibrium price falls from $3.25 to $2.50, but the equilibrium quantity increases from 250,000 to 550,000 salmon. Notice that the equilibrium quantity demanded increased, even though the demand curve did not move.
In short, good weather conditions increased supply of the California commercial salmon. The result was a higher equilibrium quantity of salmon bought and sold in the market at a lower price.
Newspapers and the Internet
According to the Pew Research Center for People and the Press, more and more people, especially younger people, are getting their news from online and digital sources. The majority of U.S. adults now own smartphones or tablets, and most of those Americans say they use them in part to get the news. From 2004 to 2012, the share of Americans who reported getting their news from digital sources increased from 24% to 39%. How has this affected consumption of print news media, and radio and television news? Figure 2 and the text below illustrates using the four-step analysis to answer this question.
Figure 2. The Print News Market: A Four-Step Analysis. A
change in tastes from print news sources to digital sources results in a
leftward shift in demand for the former. The result is a decrease in
both equilibrium price and quantity.
Step 1. Develop a demand and supply model to think about what the market looked like before the event. The demand curve D0 and the supply curve S0 show the original relationships. In this case, the analysis is performed without specific numbers on the price and quantity axis.
Step 2. Did the change described affect supply or demand? A change in tastes, from traditional news sources (print, radio, and television) to digital sources, caused a change in demand for the former.
Step 3. Was the effect on demand positive or negative? A shift to digital news sources will tend to mean a lower quantity demanded of traditional news sources at every given price, causing the demand curve for print and other traditional news sources to shift to the left, from D0 to D1.
Step 4. Compare the new equilibrium price and quantity to the original equilibrium price. The new equilibrium (E1) occurs at a lower quantity and a lower price than the original equilibrium (E0).
The decline in print news reading predates 2004. Print newspaper circulation peaked in 1973 and has declined since then due to competition from television and radio news. In 1991, 55% of Americans indicated they got their news from print sources, while only 29% did so in 2012. Radio news has followed a similar path in recent decades, with the share of Americans getting their news from radio declining from 54% in 1991 to 33% in 2012. Television news has held its own over the last 15 years, with a market share staying in the mid to upper fifties. What does this suggest for the future, given that two-thirds of Americans under 30 years old say they do not get their news from television at all?
The Interconnections and Speed of Adjustment in Real Markets
In the real world, many factors that affect demand and supply can change all at once. For example, the demand for cars might increase because of rising incomes and population, and it might decrease because of rising gasoline prices (a complementary good). Likewise, the supply of cars might increase because of innovative new technologies that reduce the cost of car production, and it might decrease as a result of new government regulations requiring the installation of costly pollution-control technology.
Moreover, rising incomes and population or changes in gasoline prices will affect many markets, not just cars. How can an economist sort out all these interconnected events? The answer lies in the ceteris paribus assumption. Look at how each economic event affects each market, one event at a time, holding all else constant. Then combine the analyses to see the net effect.A Combined Example
The U.S. Postal Service is facing difficult challenges. Compensation for postal workers tends to increase most years due to cost-of-living increases. At the same time, more and more people are using email, text, and other digital message forms such as Facebook and Twitter to communicate with friends and others. What does this suggest about the continued viability of the Postal Service? Figure 3 and the text below illustrates using the four-step analysis to answer this question.
Since this problem involves two disturbances, we need two four-step analyses, the first to analyze the effects of higher compensation for postal workers, the second to analyze the effects of many people switching from "snailmail" to email and other digital messages.
Figure 3 (a) shows the shift in supply discussed in the following steps.
Step 1. Draw a demand and supply model to illustrate what the market for the U.S. Postal Service looked like before this scenario starts. The demand curve D0 and the supply curve S0 show the original relationships.
Step 2. Did the change described affect supply or demand? Labor compensation is a cost of production. A change in production costs caused a change in supply for the Postal Service.
Step 3. Was the effect on supply positive or negative? Higher labor compensation leads to a lower quantity supplied of postal services at every given price, causing the supply curve for postal services to shift to the left, from S0 to S1.
Step 4. Compare the new equilibrium price and quantity to the original equilibrium price. The new equilibrium (E1) occurs at a lower quantity and a higher price than the original equilibrium (E0).
Figure 3 (b) shows the shift in demand discussed in the following steps.
Step 1. Draw a demand and supply model to illustrate what the market for U.S. Postal Services looked like before this scenario starts. The demand curve D0 and the supply curve S0 show the original relationships. Note that this diagram is independent from the diagram in panel (a).
Step 2. Did the change described affect supply or demand? A change in tastes away from snailmail toward digital messages will cause a change in demand for the Postal Service.
Step 3. Was the effect on supply positive or negative? Higher labor compensation leads to a lower quantity supplied of postal services at every given price, causing the supply curve for postal services to shift to the left, from D0 to D1.
Step 4. Compare the new equilibrium price and quantity to the original equilibrium price. The new equilibrium (E2) occurs at a lower quantity and a lower price than the original equilibrium (E0).
The final step in a scenario where both supply and demand shift is to combine the two individual analyses to determine what happens to the equilibrium quantity and price. Graphically, we superimpose the previous two diagrams one on top of the other, as in Figure 4.

Figure 4. Combined Effect of Decreased Demand and
Decreased Supply. Supply and demand shifts cause changes in equilibrium
price and quantity.
Following are the results:
Effect on Quantity: The effect of higher labor compensation on Postal Services because it raises the cost of production is to decrease the equilibrium quantity. The effect of a change in tastes away from snailmail is to decrease the equilibrium quantity. Since both shifts are to the left, the overall impact is a decrease in the equilibrium quantity of Postal Services (Q3). This is easy to see graphically, since Q3 is to the left of Q0.
Effect on Price: The overall effect on price is more complicated. The effect of higher labor compensation on Postal Services, because it raises the cost of production, is to increase the equilibrium price. The effect of a change in tastes away from snailmail is to decrease the equilibrium price. Since the two effects are in opposite directions, unless we know the magnitudes of the two effects, the overall effect is unclear. This is not unusual. When both curves shift, typically we can determine the overall effect on price or on quantity, but not on both. In this case, we determined the overall effect on the equilibrium quantity, but not on the equilibrium price. In other cases, it might be the opposite.
The next Clear It Up feature focuses on the difference between shifts of supply or demand and movements along a curve.
What is the difference between shifts of demand or supply versus movements along a demand or supply curve?One common mistake in applying the demand and supply framework is to confuse the shift of a demand or a supply curve with movement along a demand or supply curve. As an example, consider a problem that asks whether a drought will increase or decrease the equilibrium quantity and equilibrium price of wheat. Lee, a student in an introductory economics class, might reason:
"Well, it is clear that a drought reduces supply, so I will shift back the supply curve, as in the shift from the original supply curve S0 to S1 shown on the diagram (called Shift 1). So the equilibrium moves from E0 to E1, the equilibrium quantity is lower and the equilibrium price is higher. Then, a higher price makes farmers more likely to supply the good, so the supply curve shifts right, as shown by the shift from S1 to S2, on the diagram (shown as Shift 2), so that the equilibrium now moves from E1 to E2. The higher price, however, also reduces demand and so causes demand to shift back, like the shift from the original demand curve, D0 to D1 on the diagram (labeled Shift 3), and the equilibrium moves from E2 to E3".
Figure 5. Shifts of Demand or Supply versus Movements
along a Demand or Supply Curve. A shift in one curve never causes a
shift in the other curve. Rather, a shift in one curve causes a movement
along the second curve.
Answer: Lee's first step is correct: that is, a drought shifts back the supply curve of wheat and leads to a prediction of a lower equilibrium quantity and a higher equilibrium price. This corresponds to a movement along the original demand curve (D0), from E0 to E1. The rest of Lee's argument is wrong, because it mixes up shifts in supply with quantity supplied, and shifts in demand with quantity demanded. A higher or lower price never shifts the supply curve, as suggested by the shift in supply from S1 to S2. Instead, a price change leads to a movement along a given supply curve. Similarly, a higher or lower price never shifts a demand curve, as suggested in the shift from D0 to D1. Instead, a price change leads to a movement along a given demand curve. Remember, a change in the price of a good never causes the demand or supply curve for that good to shift.
Key Concepts and Summary
When using the supply and demand framework to think about how an event will affect the equilibrium price and quantity, proceed through four steps: (1) sketch a supply and demand diagram to think about what the market looked like before the event; (2) decide whether the event will affect supply or demand; (3) decide whether the effect on supply or demand is negative or positive, and draw the appropriate shifted supply or demand curve; (4) compare the new equilibrium price and quantity to the original ones.
Price Ceilings and Price Floors
Learning Objectives
By the end of this section, you will be able to:
- Explain price controls, price ceilings, and price floors
- Analyze demand and supply as a social adjustment mechanism
Controversy sometimes surrounds the prices and quantities established by demand and supply, especially for products that are considered necessities. In some cases, discontent over prices turns into public pressure on politicians, who may then pass legislation to prevent a certain price from climbing "too high" or falling "too low".
The demand and supply model shows how people and firms will react to the incentives provided by these laws to control prices, in ways that will often lead to undesirable consequences. Alternative policy tools can often achieve the desired goals of price control laws, while avoiding at least some of their costs and tradeoffs.
Price Ceilings
Laws that government enacts to regulate prices are called Price controls. Price controls come in two flavors. A price ceiling keeps a price from rising above a certain level (the "ceiling"), while a price floor keeps a price from falling below a certain level (the "floor"). This section uses the demand and supply framework to analyze price ceilings. The next section discusses price floors.
In many markets for goods and services, demanders outnumber suppliers. Consumers, who are also potential voters, sometimes unite behind a political proposal to hold down a certain price. In some cities, such as Albany, renters have pressed political leaders to pass rent control laws, a price ceiling that usually works by stating that rents can be raised by only a certain maximum percentage each year.
Rent control becomes a politically hot topic when rents begin to rise rapidly. Everyone needs an affordable place to live. Perhaps a change in tastes makes a certain suburb or town a more popular place to live. Perhaps locally-based businesses expand, bringing higher incomes and more people into the area. Changes of this sort can cause a change in the demand for rental housing, as Figure 1 illustrates. The original equilibrium (E0) lies at the intersection of supply curve S0 and demand curve D0, corresponding to an equilibrium price of $500 and an equilibrium quantity of 15,000 units of rental housing. The effect of greater income or a change in tastes is to shift the demand curve for rental housing to the right, as shown by the data in Table 10 and the shift from D0 to D1 on the graph. In this market, at the new equilibrium E1, the price of a rental unit would rise to $600 and the equilibrium quantity would increase to 17,000 units.
Figure 1. A Price Ceiling Example – Rent Control. The original intersection of demand and supply occurs at E0. If demand shifts from D0 to D1, the new equilibrium would be at E1 – unless
a price ceiling prevents the price from rising. If the price is not
permitted to rise, the quantity supplied remains at 15,000. However,
after the change in demand, the quantity demanded rises to 19,000,
resulting in a shortage.
Price | Original Quantity Supplied | Original Quantity Demanded | New Quantity Demanded |
---|---|---|---|
$400 | 12,000 | 18,000 | 23,000 |
$500 | 15,000 | 15,000 | 19,000 |
$600 | 17,000 | 13,000 | 17,000 |
$700 | 19,000 | 11,000 | 15,000 |
$800 | 20,000 | 10,000 | 14,000 |
Table 10. Rent Control |
Suppose that a rent control law is passed to keep the price at the original equilibrium of $500 for a typical apartment. In Figure 1,
the horizontal line at the price of $500 shows the legally fixed
maximum price set by the rent control law. However, the underlying
forces that shifted the demand curve to the right are still there. At
that price ($500), the quantity supplied remains at the same 15,000
rental units, but the quantity demanded is 19,000 rental units. In other
words, the quantity demanded exceeds the quantity supplied, so there is
a shortage of rental housing. One of the ironies of price ceilings is
that while the price ceiling was intended to help renters, there are
actually fewer apartments rented out under the price ceiling (15,000
rental units) than would be the case at the market rent of $600 (17,000
rental units).
Price ceilings do not simply benefit renters at the expense of landlords. Rather, some renters (or potential renters) lose their housing as landlords convert apartments to co-ops and condos. Even when the housing remains in the rental market, landlords tend to spend less on maintenance and on essentials like heating, cooling, hot water, and lighting. The first rule of economics is you do not get something for nothing – everything has an opportunity cost. So if renters get "cheaper" housing than the market requires, they tend to also end up with lower quality housing.
Price ceilings have been proposed for other products. For example, price ceilings to limit what producers can charge have been proposed in recent years for prescription drugs, doctor and hospital fees, the charges made by some automatic teller bank machines, and auto insurance rates. Price ceilings are enacted in an attempt to keep prices low for those who demand the product. But when the market price is not allowed to rise to the equilibrium level, quantity demanded exceeds quantity supplied, and thus a shortage occurs. Those who manage to purchase the product at the lower price given by the price ceiling will benefit, but sellers of the product will suffer, along with those who are not able to purchase the product at all. Quality is also likely to deteriorate.
Price Floors
A price floor is the lowest legal price that can be paid in markets for goods and services, labor, or financial capital. Perhaps the best-known example of a price floor is the minimum wage, which is based on the normative view that someone working full time ought to be able to afford a basic standard of living. The federal minimum wage at the end of 2014 was $7.25 per hour, which yields an income for a single person slightly higher than the poverty line. As the cost of living rises over time, the Congress periodically raises the federal minimum wage.
Price floors are sometimes called "price supports," because they support a price by preventing it from falling below a certain level. Around the world, many countries have passed laws to create agricultural price supports. Farm prices and thus farm incomes fluctuate, sometimes widely. So even if, on average, farm incomes are adequate, some years they can be quite low. The purpose of price supports is to prevent these swings.
The most common way price supports work is that the government enters the market and buys up the product, adding to demand to keep prices higher than they otherwise would be. According to the Common Agricultural Policy reform passed in 2013, the European Union (EU) will spend about 60 billion euros per year, or 67 billion dollars per year, or roughly 38% of the EU budget, on price supports for Europe's farmers from 2014 to 2020.
Figure 2 illustrates the effects of a government program that assures a price above the equilibrium by focusing on the market for wheat in Europe. In the absence of government intervention, the price would adjust so that the quantity supplied would equal the quantity demanded at the equilibrium point E0, with price P0 and quantity Q0. However, policies to keep prices high for farmers keeps the price above what would have been the market equilibrium level – the price Pf shown by the dashed horizontal line in the diagram. The result is a quantity supplied in excess of the quantity demanded (Qd). When quantity supplied exceeds quantity demanded, a surplus exists.
The high-income areas of the world, including the United States, Europe, and Japan, are estimated to spend roughly $1 billion per day in supporting their farmers. If the government is willing to purchase the excess supply (or to provide payments for others to purchase it), then farmers will benefit from the price floor, but taxpayers and consumers of food will pay the costs. Numerous proposals have been offered for reducing farm subsidies. In many countries, however, political support for subsidies for farmers remains strong. Either because this is viewed by the population as supporting the traditional rural way of life or because of the lobbying power of the agro-business industry.
For more detail on the effects price ceilings and floors have on demand and supply, see the following Clear It Up feature.

Figure 2. European Wheat Prices: A Price Floor Example. The intersection of demand (D) and supply (S) would be at the equilibrium point E0. However, a price floor set at Pf holds the price above E0
and prevents it from falling. The result of the price floor is that the
quantity supplied Qs exceeds the quantity demanded Qd. There is excess
supply, also called a surplus.
Do price ceilings and floors change demand or supply?
Neither price ceilings nor price floors cause demand or supply to change. They simply set a price that limits what can be legally charged in the market. Remember, changes in price do not cause demand or supply to change. Price ceilings and price floors can cause a different choice of quantity demanded along a demand curve, but they do not move the demand curve. Price controls can cause a different choice of quantity supplied along a supply curve, but they do not shift the supply curve.
Key Concepts and Summary
Price ceilings prevent a price from rising above a certain level. When a price ceiling is set below the equilibrium price, quantity demanded will exceed quantity supplied, and excess demand or shortages will result. Price floors prevent a price from falling below a certain level. When a price floor is set above the equilibrium price, quantity supplied will exceed quantity demanded, and excess supply or surpluses will result. Price floors and price ceilings often lead to unintended consequences.
Demand, Supply, and Efficiency
Learning Objectives
- Contrast consumer surplus, producer surplus, and social surplus
- Explain why price floors and price ceilings can be inefficient
- Analyze demand and supply as a social adjustment mechanism
The familiar demand and supply diagram holds within it the concept of economic efficiency. One typical way that economists define efficiency is when it is impossible to improve the situation of one party without imposing a cost on another. Conversely, if a situation is inefficient, it becomes possible to benefit at least one party without imposing costs on others.
Efficiency in the demand and supply model has the same basic meaning: The economy is getting as much benefit as possible from its scarce resources and all the possible gains from trade have been achieved. In other words, the optimal amount of each good and service is being produced and consumed.
Consumer Surplus, Producer Surplus, Social Surplus
Consider a market for tablet computers, as shown in Figure 1. The equilibrium price is $80 and the equilibrium quantity is 28 million. To see the benefits to consumers, look at the segment of the demand curve above the equilibrium point and to the left. This portion of the demand curve shows that at least some demanders would have been willing to pay more than $80 for a tablet.
For example, point J shows that if the price were $90, 20 million tablets would be sold. Those consumers who would have been willing to pay $90 for a tablet-based on the utility they expect to receive from it, but who were able to pay the equilibrium price of $80, clearly received a benefit beyond what they had to pay for. Remember, the demand curve traces consumers' willingness to pay for different quantities. The amount that individuals would have been willing to pay, minus the amount that they actually paid, is called consumer surplus. Consumer surplus is the area labeled F – that is, the area above the market price and below the demand curve.Figure 1. Consumer and Producer Surplus. The somewhat
triangular area labeled by F shows the area of consumer surplus, which
shows that the equilibrium price in the market was less than what many
of the consumers were willing to pay. Point J on the demand curve shows
that, even at the price of $90, consumers would have been willing to
purchase a quantity of 20 million. The somewhat triangular area labeled
by G shows the area of producer surplus, which shows that the
equilibrium price received in the market was more than what many of the
producers were willing to accept for their products. For example, point K
on the supply curve shows that at a price of $45, firms would have been
willing to supply a quantity of 14 million.
The supply curve shows the quantity that firms are willing to supply at each price. For example, point K in Figure 1
illustrates that, at $45, firms would still have been willing to supply
a quantity of 14 million. Those producers who would have been willing
to supply the tablets at $45, but who were instead able to charge the
equilibrium price of $80, clearly received an extra benefit beyond what
they required to supply the product. The amount that a seller is paid
for a good minus the seller's actual cost is called producer surplus. In Figure 1,
producer surplus is the area labeled G – that is, the area between the
market price and the segment of the supply curve below the equilibrium.
The sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus is social surplus, also referred to as economic surplus or total surplus. In Figure 1,
social surplus would be shown as the area F + G. Social surplus is
larger at equilibrium quantity and price than it would be at any other
quantity. This demonstrates the economic efficiency of the market
equilibrium. In addition, at the efficient level of output, it is
impossible to produce greater consumer surplus without reducing producer
surplus, and it is impossible to produce greater producer surplus
without reducing consumer surplus.
Inefficiency of Price Floors and Price Ceilings
The imposition of a price floor or a price ceiling will prevent a market from adjusting to its equilibrium price and quantity, and thus will create an inefficient outcome. But there is an additional twist here. Along with creating inefficiency, price floors and ceilings will also transfer some consumer surplus to producers, or some producer surplus to consumers.
Imagine that several firms develop a promising but expensive new drug for treating back pain. If this therapy is left to the market, the equilibrium price will be $600 per month and 20,000 people will use the drug, as shown in Figure 2 (a). The original level of consumer surplus is T + U and producer surplus is V + W + X. However, the government decides to impose a price ceiling of $400 to make the drug more affordable. At this price ceiling, firms in the market now produce only 15,000.
As a result, two changes occur. First, an inefficient outcome occurs and the total surplus of society is reduced. The loss in social surplus that occurs when the economy produces at an inefficient quantity is called deadweight loss. In a very real sense, it is like money thrown away that benefits no one. In Figure 2 (a), the deadweight loss is the area U + W. When deadweight loss exists, it is possible for both consumer and producer surplus to be higher, in this case because the price control is blocking some suppliers and demanders from transactions they would both be willing to make.
A second change from the price ceiling is that some of the producer surplus is transferred to consumers. After the price ceiling is imposed, the new consumer surplus is T + V, while the new producer surplus is X. In other words, the price ceiling transfers the area of surplus (V) from producers to consumers. Note that the gain to consumers is less than the loss to producers, which is just another way of seeing the deadweight loss.
Figure 2. (a) Efficiency and Price Floors and Ceilings.
The original equilibrium price is $600 with a quantity of 20,000.
Consumer surplus is T + U, and producer surplus is V + W + X. A price
ceiling is imposed at $400, so firms in the market now produce only a
quantity of 15,000. As a result, the new consumer surplus is T + V,
while the new producer surplus is X. (b) The original equilibrium is $8
at a quantity of 1,800. Consumer surplus is G + H + J, and producer
surplus is I + K. A price floor is imposed at $12, which means that
quantity demanded falls to 1,400. As a result, the new consumer surplus
is G, and the new producer surplus is H + I.
Figure 2 (b) shows a price floor example using a string of struggling movie theaters, all in the same city. The current equilibrium is $8 per movie ticket, with 1,800 people attending movies. The original consumer surplus is G + H + J, and producer surplus is I + K. The city government is worried that movie theaters will go out of business, reducing the entertainment options available to citizens, so it decides to impose a price floor of $12 per ticket. As a result, the quantity demanded of movie tickets falls to 1,400. The new consumer surplus is G, and the new producer surplus is H + I. In effect, the price floor causes the area H to be transferred from consumer to producer surplus, but also causes a deadweight loss of J + K.
This analysis shows that a price ceiling, like a law establishing rent controls, will transfer some producer surplus to consumers – which helps to explain why consumers often favor them. Conversely, a price floor like a guarantee that farmers will receive a certain price for their crops will transfer some consumer surplus to producers, which explains why producers often favor them. However, both price floors and price ceilings block some transactions that buyers and sellers would have been willing to make, and creates deadweight loss. Removing such barriers, so that prices and quantities can adjust to their equilibrium level, will increase the economy's social surplus.
Demand and Supply as a Social Adjustment Mechanism
The demand and supply model emphasizes that prices are not set only by demand or only by supply, but by the interaction between the two. In 1890, the famous economist Alfred Marshall wrote that asking whether supply or demand determined a price was like arguing "whether it is the upper or the under blade of a pair of scissors that cuts a piece of paper". The answer is that both blades of the demand and supply scissors are always involved.
The adjustments of equilibrium price and quantity in a market-oriented economy often occur without much government direction or oversight. If the coffee crop in Brazil suffers a terrible frost, then the supply curve of coffee shifts to the left and the price of coffee rises. Some people – call them the coffee addicts – continue to drink coffee and pay the higher price. Others switch to tea or soft drinks. No government commission is needed to figure out how to adjust coffee prices, which companies will be allowed to process the remaining supply, which supermarkets in which cities will get how much coffee to sell, or which consumers will ultimately be allowed to drink the brew. Such adjustments in response to price changes happen all the time in a market economy, often so smoothly and rapidly that we barely notice them.
Think for a moment of all the seasonal foods that are available and inexpensive at certain times of the year, like fresh corn in midsummer, but more expensive at other times of the year. People alter their diets and restaurants alter their menus in response to these fluctuations in prices without fuss or fanfare. For both the U.S. economy and the world economy as a whole, markets – that is, demand and supply – are the primary social mechanism for answering the basic questions about what is produced, how it is produced, and for whom it is produced.
Why Can We Not Get Enough of Organic?
Why, then, are organic foods more expensive than their conventional counterparts? The answer is a clear application of the theories of supply and demand. As people have learned more about the harmful effects of chemical fertilizers, growth hormones, pesticides and the like from large-scale factory farming, our tastes and preferences for safer, organic foods have increased. This change in tastes has been reinforced by increases in income, which allow people to purchase pricier products, and has made organic foods more mainstream. This has led to an increased demand for organic foods. Graphically, the demand curve has shifted right, and we have moved up the supply curve as producers have responded to the higher prices by supplying a greater quantity.
In addition to the movement along the supply curve, we have also had an increase in the number of farmers converting to organic farming over time. This is represented by a shift to the right of the supply curve. Since both demand and supply have shifted to the right, the resulting equilibrium quantity of organic foods is definitely higher, but the price will only fall when the increase in supply is larger than the increase in demand. We may need more time before we see lower prices in organic foods. Since the production costs of these foods may remain higher than conventional farming, because organic fertilizers and pest management techniques are more expensive, they may never fully catch up with the lower prices of non-organic foods.
As a final, specific example: The Environmental Working Group's "Dirty Dozen" list of fruits and vegetables, which test high for pesticide residue even after washing, was released in April 2013. The inclusion of strawberries on the list has led to an increase in demand for organic strawberries, resulting in both a higher equilibrium price and quantity of sales.
Key Concepts and Summary
Consumer surplus is the gap between the price that consumers are willing to pay, based on their preferences, and the market equilibrium price. Producer surplus is the gap between the price for which producers are willing to sell a product, based on their costs, and the market equilibrium price. Social surplus is the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus. Total surplus is larger at the equilibrium quantity and price than it will be at any other quantity and price. Deadweight loss is loss in total surplus that occurs when the economy produces at an inefficient quantity.