Regional Trading Blocs
Regional trading blocs have become common in recent decades. They remove trade borders between neighboring countries to expand local markets and bolster trade by streamlining regulations, tariffs, and economic policies. These blocs can also come in the form of customs unions, which essentially create one shared market between several countries and dictate trade policies between countries in the union and those outside it.
A well-designed and generally accepted CET is crucial for
the sustainability of a customs union. National tariffs must be harmonized at some agreed level, taking into
account not only the often-conflicting positions of each
member but also the various special interests within each
member. Setting the level of the CET in a consensual
manner could be a complex undertaking, entailing long
and involved negotiations between member country
governments, which are themselves subject to lobbying
by different interest groups. For instance, it took the EU
11 years (1957 to 1968) to complete its CET, and Mercosur
members took four years just to agree on their nonagricultural CET.
In many developing-country customs unions, the difficulties of agreeing on a common external tariff and on the
distribution of revenues have proved to be so great that
the resulting tariff schedules tend to include numerous
country or sector-specific exceptions and sensitive lists.
Although the CARICOM CET is largely in place, it allows
broad scope for tariff reductions and suspensions, as well
as for national derogations. The CET in Mercosur does
not cover all sectors, and it includes special regimes for the
automotive and sugar sectors. In some CUs, temporary
national exemptions are allowed – for example, EAC
members Kenya and Tanzania were allowed to unilaterally
reduce tariffs on selected grain imports. Derogations and
safeguards are widely used in most CUs. Not only can
these exceptions reduce the transparency and effectiveness
of the CU, but they also can complicate trade negotiations
and increase transaction costs. Furthermore, they reintroduce the potential for trade deflection – the very phenomenon that the CU is designed to prevent.
Like most other forms of regional integration agreements, a CU is inherently preferential and is, thus, discriminatory against third parties. As argued in the previous section, the economic impact of a CU will be closely related to
the degree of discrimination, which depends on the CET
level that is selected. The higher the CET, the more trade
diversionary will the union be. An important question is
thus whether a CU provides incentives for selecting higher
or lower external tariffs than those in, say, an FTA. The
existing theoretical and empirical literature does not provide
an unequivocal answer to this question. The result seems to
depend on the way preferences (or objective functions) are
aggregated across members and within each member.
A number of analysts have demonstrated that an FTA
may create downward pressure on external tariffs. For instance, Baldwin and Freund (ch. 6 in
this volume) argue that preferential trade liberalization
in an FTA tends to make tariffs against nonmembers'
third-nation tariffs more distortionary and that it creates
an incentive for FTA members to reoptimize their most favored nation (MFN) tariffs by making them more uniform and lower. (This is referred to as the "uniform tax
rate principle"). In a related fashion, if trade diversion
becomes apparent (i.e., if a country sees itself importing
a good from a partner country at a higher cost than the
cost of similar goods from nonmembers), an FTA member has the flexibility to cut tariffs on these third-party
imports. Similarly, the potential for trade deflection may
lead high-tariff countries to cut tariffs to just below the level
of their partners' rates to prevent imports from going
through low-tariff countries that would otherwise capture
the tariff revenue. In addition, lowering import tariffs on
inputs used in producing exports to other FTA members
can render exporters more competitive. Do these arguments apply to CUs?
An often-stated objective of most customs unions
among developing countries is to promote a harmonized
reduction in internal and external trade barriers in order
to better integrate the region into the multilateral trading
system. There are, however, arguments that seem to suggest that CUs create pressures for more protectionism.
Like other integration initiatives, CUs permit member
countries to combine their market size and thereby increase
their market power. Since trade policy is set jointly, this
measure could strengthen their incentive to adopt high
CETs in order to improve their terms of trade. That is,
they can reduce global demand for an imported product,
and thereby decrease the import price, by charging higher
tariffs. The larger the size of the union, the stronger this
proprotectionist effect will be.
Furthermore, if CU members negotiate effectively as a
bloc, they can pool their negotiating power and enhance it
against the rest of the world, thus affecting the outcome of
negotiations. Given the mercantilist nature of trade negotiations, increased negotiating power is likely to lead to a
more protectionist outcome (in exchange for better market
access). It could also be argued that nonmembers will act in
a more conciliatory way when negotiating with a (single,
large) customs union than with separate FTA members, and
the result will be smaller requests for concessions.
The internal process of decision making within the CU
could also place upward pressure on tariffs. The joint, consensual determination of the external tariffs may provide
incentives to agree on higher CETs, since these imply
higher preference margins and benefit partners' firms.
(Protection is afforded to all producers in all CU member
countries.) CU members will internalize this fact and will
choose a higher external tariff (Freund and Ornelas 2010).
Accordingly, one can think of a situation in which each
CU member feels strongly about protecting a particular
sector but would like lower tariffs on the other sectors. As Winters (1996) argues, this may create a prisoner's-dilemma
outcome under which the CET would provide high protection in all sectors, even though each country would be better
off with low protection in all sectors.
The establishment of a CU also changes the power of
lobbies, but it is not clear whether the result will be
stronger or weaker demand for protection. It is possible
that lobbying pressure within a CU may be diluted, compared with national lobbying for protection within an
FTA. As Winters (1996) suggests, it is more costly to lobby
for a tariff increase in a CU than in an individual FTA
member country because there may be more opposition to
overcome or more representatives to influence. Moreover,
the returns to lobbying activities are less under a CU, given
that an extra 1 percent tariff protection becomes available
to all members. Panagariya and Findlay (1996) provide a
formal treatment of the argument that a customs union is
a more effective instrument for diluting the power of
interest groups than is an FTA. The high cost and low
returns of lobbying under a CU could lead to a free-rider
problem in lobbying, and all lobbying could end up taking
place in one country. The author finds that such a process
would yield a lower (common) external tariff under a CU
than under an FTA. The larger the size of the customs
union, the lower the resulting (lobbied) level of common
external tariff would be.
The argument could, of course, cut in the other direction. In some sectors, lobbyists in different member
countries may be able to overcome the free-rider problem, pool their resources, and cooperate. This is likely to
happen in sectors in which they produce relatively similar
goods (say, in agriculture) and where there is little intrabloc trade flow. In this case, the national lobbies would be
able to organize themselves into a regional lobby, and the
resulting common external tariff would be higher in a CU
relative to what would prevail in the individual markets
under an FTA.
The degree of "permanence" of the policy outcomes will
also affect the incentives for, and the amount of, lobbying.
An FTA does not require member countries to immediately
adjust their external tariffs, and it preserves discretion for a
country to adjust its trade policy in the future. By contrast,
a CU requires both tariff adjustments and a relatively
longer-term commitment to the trade policy jointly agreed
on by the CU members – the CET. It is therefore likely that
lobbying for protection would be stronger during the
negotiation and establishment of a CU than in the case of
an FTA. Also, the difficulties in renegotiating or readjusting
the CET could lead to the emergence of less transparent
nontariff barriers that would be implemented at the
national (instead of the regional) level.
Overall, whether opting for a CU leads to higher external
tariffs remains an open question. A number of arguments
seem to suggest that CUs may provide more protectionist
pressures than FTAs. This, however, remains an empirical
question to which the existing literature has not been able to
provide an unequivocal answer.