Fiscal Policy, Investment, and Economic Growth
Read this text on the effect crowding out has on physical capital investment, the relationship between budget deficits and interest rates, and why economic growth is tied to investments in physical and human capital and technology.
The underpinnings of economic growth are investments in physical capital, human capital, and technology, all set in an economic environment where firms and individuals can react to the incentives provided by well-functioning markets and flexible prices. Government borrowing can reduce the financial capital available for private firms to invest in physical capital. However, government spending can also encourage certain elements of long-term growth, such as spending on roads or water systems, on education, or on research and development that creates new technology.
Crowding Out Physical Capital Investment
A larger budget deficit will increase the demand for financial capital. If private savings and the trade balance remain the same, then less financial capital will be available for private investment in physical capital. When government borrowing soaks up available financial capital and leaves less for private investment in physical capital, economists call the result crowding out.
To understand the potential impact of crowding out, consider the U.S. economy's situation before the exceptional circumstances of the recession that started in late 2007. In 2005, for example, the budget deficit was roughly 3% of GDP. Private investment by firms in the U.S. economy has hovered in the range of 14% to 18% of GDP in recent decades. However, in any given year, roughly half of U.S. investment in physical capital just replaces machinery and equipment that has worn out or become technologically obsolete. Only about half represents an increase in the total quantity of physical capital in the economy. Investment in new physical capital in any year is about 7% to 9% of GDP. In this situation, even U.S. budget deficits in the range of 3% of GDP can potentially crowd out a substantial share of new investment spending. Conversely, a smaller budget deficit (or an increased budget surplus) increases the pool of financial capital available for private investment.
Figure 18.7 shows the patterns of U.S. budget deficits and private investment since 1980. If greater government deficits lead to less private investment in physical capital, and reduced government deficits or budget surpluses lead to more investment in physical capital, these two lines should move up and down simultaneously. This pattern occurred in the late 1990s and early 2000s. The U.S. federal budget went from a deficit of 2.2% of GDP in 1995 to a budget surplus of 2.4% of GDP in 2000 – a swing of 4.6% of GDP. From 1995 to 2000, private investment in physical capital rose from 15% to 18% of GDP – a rise of 3% of GDP. Then, when the U.S. government again started running budget deficits in the early 2000s, less financial capital became available for private investment, and the rate of private investment fell back to about 15% of GDP by 2003. However, in more recent years, in the 2010s, after the economy recovered from the Great Recession, private investment as a share of GDP increased even as deficits slightly worsened, especially around 2016. And while the deficit increased substantially in 2020, private investment as a share of GDP did not.
Figure 18.7 U.S. Budget Deficits/Surpluses and Private Investment The connection between private savings and flows of international capital plays a role in budget deficits and surpluses. Consequently, government borrowing and private investment sometimes rise and fall together. For example, the 1990s show a pattern in which reduced government borrowing helped to reduce crowding out so that more funds were available for private investment.
This argument does not claim that a
government's budget deficits will exactly shadow its national rate of
private investment; after all, we must account for private savings and
inflows of foreign financial investment. In the mid-1980s, for example,
government budget deficits increased substantially without a
corresponding drop in private investment. In 2009, nonresidential
private fixed investment dropped by $300 billion from its previous level
of $1,941 billion in 2008, primarily because, during a recession, firms
lacked both the funds and the incentive to invest. Investment growth
between 2009 and 2014 averaged approximately 5.9% to $2,210.5
billion – only slightly above its 2008 level, according to the Bureau of
Economic Analysis. During that same period, interest rates dropped from
3.94% to less than a quarter percent. The Federal Reserve took
dramatic action to prevent a depression by increasing the money supply
by lowering short-term interest rates. The "crowding out" of
private investment due to government borrowing to finance expenditures
appears to have been suspended after the Great Recession.
The Interest Rate Connection
Assume that government borrowing of substantial amounts will have an effect on the quantity of private investment. How will this affect interest rates in financial markets? In Figure 18.8, the original equilibrium (E0), where the demand curve (D0) for financial capital intersects with the supply curve (S0), occurs at an interest rate of 5% and an equilibrium quantity equal to 20% of GDP. However, as the government budget deficit increases, the demand curve for financial capital shifts from D0 to D1. The new equilibrium (E1) occurs at an interest rate of 6% and an equilibrium quantity of 21% of GDP.
Figure 18.8 Budget Deficits and Interest Rates In the financial market, an increase in government borrowing can shift the demand curve for financial capital to the right from D0 to D1. As the equilibrium interest rate shifts from E0 to E1, the interest rate rises from 5% to 6% in this example. The higher interest rate is one economic mechanism by which government borrowing can crowd out private investment.
A survey of economic studies on the
connection between government borrowing and interest rates in the U.S.
economy suggests that an increase of 1% in the budget deficit will lead
to a rise in interest rates of between 0.5 and 1.0%, with other factors held
equal. In turn, a higher interest rate tends to discourage firms from
making physical capital investments. One reason government budget
deficits crowd out private investment, therefore, is the increase in
interest rates. There are, however, economic studies that show a limited
connection between the two (at least in the United States). Still, as the
budget deficit grows, the dangers of rising interest rates become more
real.
At this point, you may wonder about the Federal Reserve. After all, can the Federal Reserve not use expansionary monetary policy to reduce interest rates, or in this case, to prevent interest rates from rising? This useful question emphasizes the importance of considering how fiscal and monetary policies work in relation to each other. Imagine a central bank faced with a government that is running large budget deficits, causing a rise in interest rates and crowding out private investment. Suppose the budget deficits are increasing aggregate demand when the economy is already producing near potential GDP, threatening an inflationary increase in price levels. In that case, the central bank may react with a contractionary monetary policy. In this situation, the higher interest rates from the government borrowing would be made even higher by contractionary monetary policy, and the government borrowing might crowd out a great deal of private investment.
Alternatively, if the budget deficits are increasing aggregate demand when the economy is producing substantially less than the potential GDP, an inflationary increase in the price level is not much of a danger, and the central bank might react with expansionary monetary policy. In this situation, higher interest rates from government borrowing would be largely offset by lower interest rates from expansionary monetary policy, and there would be little crowding out of private investment.
However, even a central bank cannot erase the overall message of the national savings and investment identity. If government borrowing rises, then private investment must fall, or private saving must rise, or the trade deficit must rise. By reacting with contractionary or expansionary monetary policy, the central bank can only help to determine which of these outcomes is likely.
Public Investment in Physical Capital
Government can invest in physical capital
directly: roads and bridges; water supply and sewers; seaports and
airports; schools and hospitals; plants that generate electricity, like
hydroelectric dams or windmills; telecommunications facilities; and
military weapons. In 2021, the United States spent about $146 billion on
transportation, including highways, mass transit, and airports. Table 18.1
shows the federal government's total outlay for 2021 for major public
physical capital investments in the United States. We have omitted
physical capital related to the military or to residences where people
live from this table because the focus here is on public investments
that have a direct effect on raising output in the private sector.
Type of Public Physical Capital | Federal Outlays 2014 | Federal Outlays 2021 |
---|---|---|
Transportation | $91,915 | $146,156 |
Community and regional development | $20,670 | $83,619 |
Natural resources and the environment | $36,171 | $40,691 |
Education, training, employment, and social services | $90,615 | $236,723 |
Other | $37,282 | $41,227 |
Total | $276,653 | $548,416 |
Table
18.1
Grants for Major Physical Capital Investment, 2014 and 2021, in $ Millions
Public physical capital investment of this
sort can increase the economy's output and productivity. An economy with
reliable roads and electricity will be able to produce more. However,
it is hard to quantify how much government investment in physical
capital will benefit the economy because the government responds to
political as well as economic incentives. When a firm makes an
investment in physical capital, it is subject to the discipline of the
market: If it does not receive a positive return on investment, the firm
may lose money or even go out of business.
In some cases, lawmakers make investments in physical capital as a way of spending money in key politicians' districts. The result may be unnecessary roads or office buildings. Even if a project is useful and necessary, it might be done in a way that is excessively costly because local contractors who make campaign contributions to politicians appreciate the extra business. Alternatively, governments sometimes do not make the investments they should because a decision to spend on infrastructure does not need to just make economic sense. It must be politically popular as well. Managing public investment cost-effectively can be difficult.
Suppose a government decides to finance an investment in public physical capital with higher taxes or lower government spending in other areas. In that case, it need not worry that it is directly crowding out private investment. Indirectly, however, higher household taxes could cut down on the level of private savings available and have a similar effect. Suppose a government decides to finance an investment in public physical capital by borrowing. In that case, it may end up increasing the quantity of public physical capital at the cost of crowding out investment in private physical capital, which could be more beneficial to the economy.
Public Investment in Human Capital
In most countries, the government plays a large role in society's investment in human capital through the education system. A highly educated and skilled workforce contributes to a higher rate of economic growth. For the low-income nations of the world, additional investment in human capital seems likely to increase productivity and growth. For the United States, critics have raised tough questions about how much increases in government spending on education will improve the actual level of education.
Among economists, discussions of education reform often begin with some uncomfortable facts. As Figure 18.9
shows, spending per student for kindergarten through grade 12 (K–12)
increased substantially in real dollars through 2010, declined slightly
in 2011 and 2012, and began rising again after that through 2020.
However, as measured by standardized tests like the SAT, the level of
student academic achievement has barely budged in recent decades. On
international tests, U.S. students lag behind students from many other
countries. (Of course, test scores are an imperfect measure of education
for a variety of reasons. It would be difficult, however, to argue that
there are no real problems in the U.S. education system and that the
tests are just inaccurate).
Figure 18.9 Total Spending for Elementary, Secondary, and Vocational Education (1998–2020) in the United States The graph shows that government spending on education was continually increasing up until 2006 when it leveled off until 2008 when it increased dramatically. Since 2010, spending has steadily decreased. (Source: Office of Management and Budget)
The fact that increased financial
resources have not brought greater measurable gains in student
performance has led some education experts to question whether the
problems may be due to structure, not just to the resources spent.
Other government programs seek to increase human capital either before or after the K–12 education system. Programs for early childhood education, like the federal Head Start program, are directed at families where the parents may have limited educational and financial resources. The government also offers substantial support for universities and colleges. For example, in the United States, about 60% of students take at least a few college or university classes beyond the high school level. In Germany and Japan, about half of all students take classes beyond the comparable high school level. In the countries of Latin America, only about one student in four takes classes beyond the high school level, and in the nations of sub-Saharan Africa, only about one student in 20.
Not all spending on educational human capital needs to happen through the government: many college students in the United States pay a substantial share of the cost of their education. Suppose low-income countries of the world are going to experience a widespread increase in their education levels for grade-school children. In that case, government spending seems likely to play a substantial role. For the U.S. economy and for other high-income countries, the primary focus at this time is more on how to get a bigger return from existing spending on education and how to improve the performance of the average high school graduate rather than dramatic increases in education spending.
How Fiscal Policy Can Improve Technology
Research and development (R&D) efforts are the lifeblood of new technology. According to the National Science Foundation, federal outlays for research, development, and physical plant improvements to various governmental agencies have remained at an average of 8.8% of GDP. About one-fifth of U.S. R&D spending goes to defense and space-oriented research. Although defense-oriented R&D spending may sometimes produce consumer-oriented spinoffs, R&D that is aimed at producing new weapons is less likely to benefit the civilian economy than direct civilian R&D spending.
Fiscal policy can encourage R&D using either direct spending or tax policy. The government could spend more on the R&D that it carries out in government laboratories, as well as expanding federal R&D grants to universities and colleges, nonprofit organizations, and the private sector. By 2014, the federal share of R&D outlays totaled $135.5 billion, or about 4% of the federal government's total budget outlays, according to data from the National Science Foundation. Fiscal policy can also support R&D through tax incentives, which allow firms to reduce their tax bill as they increase spending on research and development.
Summary of Fiscal Policy, Investment, and Economic Growth
Investment in physical capital, human capital, and new technology is essential for long-term economic growth, as Table 18.2 summarizes. In a market-oriented economy, private firms will undertake most of the investment in physical capital, and fiscal policy should seek to avoid a long series of outsized budget deficits that might crowd out such investment. We will see the effects of many growth-oriented policies very gradually over time, as students are better educated, we make physical capital investments, and man invents and implements new technologies.
Physical Capital | Human Capital | New Technology | |
---|---|---|---|
Private Sector | New investment in property and equipment | On-the-job training | Research and development |
Public Sector | Public infrastructure | Public education Job training | Research and development are encouraged through private sector incentives and direct spending. |
Table
18.2
Investment Role of Public and Private Sector in a Market Economy
Bring It Home
Financing Higher Education
According to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, between 1980 and 2020, the average tuition and fees at a 4-year public university increased from $738 to $9,349. This represents a more than 12-fold increase in this 40 year period. To put this increase into perspective, median yearly household income in the U.S. has increased from about $20,000 to $67,000 during the same time – about a 3.5-fold increase. Clearly, college is becoming increasingly expensive, even as it continues to provide the same benefits that were mentioned at the beginning of this chapter by President Lyndon B. Johnson.
Crucial to the mission of higher education is the Pell Grant program, which was initiated by President Johnson as part of the Higher Education Act of 1965. But Pell Grant amounts have not adequately kept up with the rising costs of college tuition and fees. As part of President Joe Biden's Build Back Better proposal, the maximum Pell Grant award would increase to $7,045 between 2022–2025, representing an 8.5% increase, which is one of the largest 1-year increases in the last 20 years (the largest increase occurred between 2009 and 2010, during President Barack Obama's term in office). The original proposal also aimed to allow for Deferred Action for Childhood Arrivals program participants to benefit from the awards, through 2030.
Source: Rice University, https://openstax.org/books/principles-macroeconomics-3e/pages/18-4-fiscal-policy-investment-and-economic-growth
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 License.